771 research outputs found
Bank Liquidity, Interbank Markets, and Monetary Policy
A major lesson of the recent financial crisis is that the interbank lending market is crucial for banks facing large uncertainty regarding their liquidity needs. This paper studies the efficiency of the interbank lending market in allocating funds. We consider two different types of liquidity shocks leading to diĀ¤erent implications for optimal policy by the central bank. We show that, when confronted with a distribu- tional liquidity-shock crisis that causes a large disparity in the liquidity held among banks, the central bank should lower the interbank rate. This view implies that the traditional tenet prescribing the separation between prudential regulation and mon- etary policy should be abandoned. In addition, we show that, during an aggregate liquidity crisis, central banks should manage the aggregate volume of liquidity. Two diĀ¤erent instruments, interest rates and liquidity injection, are therefore required to cope with the two diĀ¤erent types of liquidity shocks. Finally, we show that failure to cut interest rates during a crisis erodes financial stability by increasing the risk of bank runs.bank liquidity;interbank markets;central bank policy;financial fragility;bank runs
Clearing algorithms and network centrality
I show that the solution of a standard clearing model commonly used in
contagion analyses for financial systems can be expressed as a specific form of
a generalized Katz centrality measure under conditions that correspond to a
system-wide shock. This result provides a formal explanation for earlier
empirical results which showed that Katz-type centrality measures are closely
related to contagiousness. It also allows assessing the assumptions that one is
making when using such centrality measures as systemic risk indicators. I
conclude that these assumptions should be considered too strong and that, from
a theoretical perspective, clearing models should be given preference over
centrality measures in systemic risk analyses
Densely Entangled Financial Systems
In [1] Zawadoski introduces a banking network model in which the asset and
counter-party risks are treated separately and the banks hedge their assets
risks by appropriate OTC contracts. In his model, each bank has only two
counter-party neighbors, a bank fails due to the counter-party risk only if at
least one of its two neighbors default, and such a counter-party risk is a low
probability event. Informally, the author shows that the banks will hedge their
asset risks by appropriate OTC contracts, and, though it may be socially
optimal to insure against counter-party risk, in equilibrium banks will {\em
not} choose to insure this low probability event.
In this paper, we consider the above model for more general network
topologies, namely when each node has exactly 2r counter-party neighbors for
some integer r>0. We extend the analysis of [1] to show that as the number of
counter-party neighbors increase the probability of counter-party risk also
increases, and in particular the socially optimal solution becomes privately
sustainable when each bank hedges its risk to at least n/2 banks, where n is
the number of banks in the network, i.e., when 2r is at least n/2, banks not
only hedge their asset risk but also hedge its counter-party risk.Comment: to appear in Network Models in Economics and Finance, V. Kalyagin, P.
M. Pardalos and T. M. Rassias (editors), Springer Optimization and Its
Applications series, Springer, 201
How liquid are banks : some evidence from the United Kingdom
This paper uses quantitative balance sheet liquidity analysis, based upon modified versions of the BCBS 1 and Moodyās 2 models, to provide indicators which would alarm the UK banksā short and long-term liquidity positions respectively. These information will also underpin other research related liquidity risk to banksā lending and performance. Our framework accurately reflect UK banksā liquidity positions under both normal and stress scenarios based on the consistent accounting information under IFRS. It has significant contribution on Basel III liquidity ratios calculation. The study also presents fundamental financial information to facilitate analysis of banksā business models and funding strategies.
Using data for the period 2005-2010, we provide evidence that there have been variable liquidity strains across the UK banks in our sample. The estimated results show that Barclays Bank was the only bank to maintain a healthy short-term liquidity position throughout the sample period; while HSBC remained liquid in the short term, in both normal and stress conditions, except in 2008 and 2010. RBS, meanwhile, maintained healthy long-term liquidity positions from 2008 after receiving government injections of capital. And Santander UK was also able to post healthy long-term liquidity positions, except in 2009. However, the other four banks, the Bank of Scotland, Lloyds TSB, Natwest, and Standard Chartered,
proved illiquid, on both a short-term and long-term basis, throughout the six-year period, with Natwest being by far the worst performer
Do bad borrowers hurt good borrowers? A model of biased banking competition
This paper explores a two-bank model in which, first, one bank correctly estimates the probability of low-quality loan repayment while the other overestimates it, and second, both banks have identical convex costs when granting loans. In this context of optimistically biased banking competition, we show how the unbiased bank follows the biased competitor as long as the bias of the latter is not too large. This would favour bad borrowers, who get better credit conditions at the expense of good borrowers. As a consequence, the presence of a biased bank increases welfare as long as the expected default rate is sufficiently high. Contrariwise, in subprime markets, biased banking competition would be socially harmful.info:eu-repo/semantics/publishedVersio
On the Computational Complexity of Measuring Global Stability of Banking Networks
Threats on the stability of a financial system may severely affect the
functioning of the entire economy, and thus considerable emphasis is placed on
the analyzing the cause and effect of such threats. The financial crisis in the
current and past decade has shown that one important cause of instability in
global markets is the so-called financial contagion, namely the spreading of
instabilities or failures of individual components of the network to other,
perhaps healthier, components. This leads to a natural question of whether the
regulatory authorities could have predicted and perhaps mitigated the current
economic crisis by effective computations of some stability measure of the
banking networks. Motivated by such observations, we consider the problem of
defining and evaluating stabilities of both homogeneous and heterogeneous
banking networks against propagation of synchronous idiosyncratic shocks given
to a subset of banks. We formalize the homogeneous banking network model of
Nier et al. and its corresponding heterogeneous version, formalize the
synchronous shock propagation procedures, define two appropriate stability
measures and investigate the computational complexities of evaluating these
measures for various network topologies and parameters of interest. Our results
and proofs also shed some light on the properties of topologies and parameters
of the network that may lead to higher or lower stabilities.Comment: to appear in Algorithmic
Why Commercial Banks Held Excess Reserves: The Japanese Experience of the Late '90s
We investigated, empirically, why Japanese banks held excess reserves in the late 1990s. Specifically, we pin down two factors explaining the demand for excess reserves: a low short-term interest rate, or call rate, and the fragile financial health of banks. The virtually zero call rate increased the demand for excess reserves substantially, and a high bad loans ratio largely contributed to the increase in excess reserve holdings. We found that the holdings of excess reserves would fall by half if the call rate were to be raised to its level prior to the adoption of the zero-interest-rate policy, and the bad loans ratio were to fall by 50%
Deposit Insurance in General Equilibrium
We study the consequences and optimal design of bank deposit insurance in a general equilibrium model. The model involves two production sectors. One sector is financed by issuing bonds to risk-averse households. Firms in the other sector are monitored and financed by banks. Households fund banks through deposits and equity. Deposits are explicitly insured by a de- posit insurance fund. Any remaining shortfall is implicitly guaranteed by the government. The deposit insurance fund charges banks a premium per unit of deposits whereas the government finances any necessary bail-outs by lump-sum taxation of households. When the deposit insurance premium is actuarially fair or higher than actuarially fair, two types of equilibria emerge: One type of equilibria supports the socially optimal (Arrow-Debreu) allo- cation, and the other type does not. In the latter case, bank lending is too large relative to equity and the probability that the banking system collapses is positive. Next, we show that a judicious combination of deposit insurance and reinsurance eliminates all non-optimal equilibrium allocations
- ā¦