352 research outputs found

    Vygotsky’s natural history of signs

    Get PDF
    The paper organizes the topic of signs in Lev Vygotsky’s various writings into a coherent whole in order to study signs’ role in child development. Vygotsky related conventional signs that have their origin in interpersonal communication, and are subject to cultural history taking place over generations during historical time, to psychological functioning of individual human beings. Vygotsky’s “natural history of signs” is the study of how symbolic activity appears and develops. The paper outlines the process of inclusion of symbols within the behaviour of the child and gives an account of various changes in psychological functions and their interrelations that it brings along. In cultural development specifically human forms of behaviour appear, and children’s relationship to social and material environment is changed qualitatively. Vygotsky outlines the formation of sign use and analyses its developmental steps. Vygotsky’s approach explains how the use of various sign systems shapes both the cognitive processes in the person, the child, and the cognitive development as a whole. Vygotsky’s approach to signs is presented within the conceptual framework of its time

    Differentiation of language functions during language acquisition based on Roman Jakobson’s communication model

    Get PDF
    The paper uses Roman Jakobson’s conceptual framework to study the development of communication of children. It sets out to explain how cardinal functions of verbal messages – referential, emotive, conative, phatic, metalingual and poetic – understood in terms of Jakobson’s communication model – progressively differentiate during children’s language acquisition. The differentiation of these functions is apparent in changes in children’s use of language, as it corresponds to the gradual formation and adoption of various linguistic structures in the development of speech. Children’s acquisition of the use of grammatical subject and predicate, corresponding to the appearance of specifically metalingual speech, among other linguistic structures, is related to children’s adaptation to the linguistic environment. The article relates differentiation of metalingual and poetic functions to the development of children’s thinking using the example of crib talk

    SĂŒdame areng ja kaasasĂŒndinud rikked. Biomehaaniline perspektiiv

    Get PDF
    SĂŒdamerikked ilmnevad umbes 1%-l elusalt sĂŒndinud lastest. Uuringud on nĂ€idanud, et kĂ”igist kaasasĂŒndinud riketest esinevad kĂ”ige sagedamini sĂŒdamerikked. Viimase aja uuringud on esile toonud mitmeid pĂ”hjusi, mis soodustavad kaasasĂŒndinud sĂŒdamerikete kujunemist. Ühelt poolt vĂ”ib sellel olla molekulaarbioloogiline pĂ”hjus – geenimutatsioon –, mis on tingitud nukleotiidide muutustest geenides (1). Teiselt poolt on mĂ”juteguriks emakasisene keskkond, mida vĂ”ib mĂ”jutada ema eluviis ja kĂ€itumine, nĂ€iteks alkoholitarbimine, suitsetamine, narkootikumide, ravimite tarvitamine (2, 3). Samuti vĂ”ib embrĂŒo areng olla hĂ€iritud mĂ”ningate toitainete puudusest emal, nĂ€iteks foolhappe puudus ja sellest tulenev homotsĂŒsteiinisisalduse suurenemine veres (4). Kirjeldatud tegurid vĂ”ivad mĂ”jutada loote arengut vĂ€ga varajases perioodis, kui ema veel ei teagi, et ta on rase. Harilikult tuvastab naine raseduse 5.–6. nĂ€dalal pĂ€rast viljastumist. Tuksuv sĂŒda ja vereringe kujuneb lootel juba 3. viljastumisjĂ€rgsel nĂ€dalal (16.–21. pĂ€eval). Seega vĂ”ivad sĂŒdame arengut mĂ”jutavad tegurid toimida juba siis, kui naine ei olegi oma rasedusest teadlik. SĂŒdamerikete kujunemise pĂ”hjuste selgitamiseks on vaja uurida loote arengu vĂ€ga varajasi perioode. Eesti Arst 2013; 92(2):80–8

    Introduction: Framing nature and culture

    Get PDF
    Introduction: Framing nature and culture

    Learning Effects of the Flipped Classroom in a Principles of Microeconomics Course Running Header: Flipped Principles of Micro

    Get PDF
    The authors of this article estimate the learning effects of the flipped classroom format using data from 16 sections of principles of microeconomics over a 4-year period. The experimental design is unique in that two treatment and two control sections were taught during the fall semester in four consecutive years. Further, the instructor switched the time of day when the treatment and control sections were taught each year. Controlling for gender, ACT score, a normed high school GPA, Pell Grant award, time of day, and initial knowledge of economics, the authors find no evidence of increased learning using end-of-semester measures for students in the flipped classroom in comparison to sections with a moderate amount of active learning

    Measuring Faculty Teaching Effectiveness Using Conditional Fixed Effects

    Get PDF
    Using a dataset of 48 faculty members and 88 courses over 26 semesters, the authors estimate Student Evaluation of Teaching (SET) ratings that are conditional on a multitude of course, faculty, and student attributes. They find that ratings are lower for required courses and those where students report a lower prior level of interest. Controlling for these variables substantially alters the SET ratings for many instructors. The average absolute value of the difference between the faculty ratings controlling just for time effects and fully conditional ratings is nearly one-half of a standard deviation in the students’ rating of how much they learned. This difference produces a change in quartile rank for over half the sample across two summary course evaluation measures

    Could tariffs be pro-cyclical?

    Get PDF
    Conventional wisdom says that tariffs are counter-cyclical. We analyze the relationship between business cycles and applied MFN tariffs using a disaggregated product-level panel dataset covering 72 countries between 2000 and 2011. Strikingly, and counter to conventional wisdom, we find that tariffs are pro-cyclical. Further investigation reveals that this pro-cyclicality is driven by the tariff setting behavior of developing countries; tariffs are acyclical in developed countries. We present evidence that pro-cyclical market power drives the pro-cyclicality of tariffs in developing countries, providing further evidence of the importance of terms of trade motivations in explaining trade policy

    Costly distribution and the non-equivalence of tariffs and quotas

    Get PDF
    When governments impose a quota or tariff on imports, it is well known that the resulting rents and revenues trigger costly rent-seeking and revenue-seeking activities, which are welfare-reducing and may be economically more significant than the efficiency losses resulting from the protectionist-induced resource misallocation. Repeated interaction among firms can eliminate wasteful rent- and revenue-seeking expenditures through cooperation. We show that while aggregate outcomes are equivalent under tariffs and quotas if cooperation arises, the conditions under which cooperation arises differ by policy. This difference arises because a firm must incur additional cost to physically import and distribute the goods associated with additional quota licenses, whereas there is no such cost when it comes to consuming additional tariff revenue. Thus, quotas and tariffs are non-equivalent. We provide a simple sufficient condition under which cooperative elimination of rent-seeking under quotas is easier than cooperative elimination of revenue-seeking under tariffs and therefore a quota is the preferred policy whenever the policy admits cooperation

    Domestic political competition and pro-cyclical import protection

    Get PDF
    Governments, especially in developing countries, routinely practice binding overhang (i.e. setting applied tariffs below binding WTO commitments) and frequently move applied tariffs for given products up and down over the business cycle. Moreover, applied tariffs are pro-cyclical in developing countries. We explain this phenomenon using a dynamic theory of lobbying between domestic interest groups. Applied tariffs are pro-cyclical when high-tariff interests (e.g. import-competing industries) capture the government: these groups concede lower tariffs to low-tariff interest groups (e.g. exporting firms or firms using imported intermediate inputs) during recessions because recessions lower the opportunity cost of lobbying and thereby generate a stronger lobbying threat
    • 

    corecore