999 research outputs found

    Monetary impacts and overshooting of agricultural prices in a transition economy

    Get PDF
    This research focused on the time adjustment paths of the exchange rate and prices in response to unanticipated monetary shocks. Johansen’s cointegration test along with a vector error correction model was employed, to investigate whether agricultural prices overshoot in a transition economy. The empirical results indicate that agricultural prices adjust faster than industrial prices to innovations in the money supply, affecting relative prices in the short run, but strict long-run money neutrality does not hold

    World prices and domestic food price spikes

    Get PDF
    In this paper we aim to assess the mechanics of the global food price increases experienced in the recent years, most profoundly during the 2007-2008 food price spikes. At this stage, we aim to test, whether there is an empirically assessable relationship between World agricultural commodity prices, World oil prices and Hungarian producer and consumer food prices. After briefly discussing the background of the food price surge, and some studies empirically assessing it, we estimate a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) with two long-run relationships, modelling vertical and horizontal price relationships (price transmissions). Preliminary results express (as somewhat expected for a small open economy as Hungary) that global developments have direct and significant effects upon price levels in Hungary regardless whether a vertical or horizontal price dimension is used. Further research will focus on determination of the magnitude, speed of occurrence and duration (needed to return to equilibrium) of the abovementioned global shifters express upon domestic agricultural and food price levels

    Pinning Down versus Density

    Get PDF
    The pinning down number pd(X) {pd}(X) of a topological space XX is the smallest cardinal Îș\kappa such that for any neighborhood assignment U:X→τXU:X\to \tau_X there is a set A∈[X]ÎșA\in [X]^\kappa with A∩U(x)≠∅A\cap U(x)\ne\emptyset for all x∈Xx\in X. Clearly, c(X)≀pd(X)≀d(X)(X) \le {pd}(X) \le {d}(X). Here we prove that the following statements are equivalent: (1) 2Îș<Îș+ω2^\kappa<\kappa^{+\omega} for each cardinal Îș\kappa; (2) d(X)=pd(X){d}(X)={pd}(X) for each Hausdorff space XX; (3) d(X)=pd(X){d}(X)={pd}(X) for each 0-dimensional Hausdorff space XX. This answers two questions of Banakh and Ravsky. The dispersion character Δ(X)\Delta(X) of a space XX is the smallest cardinality of a non-empty open subset of XX. We also show that if pd(X)<d(X){pd}(X)<{d}(X) then XX has an open subspace YY with pd(Y)<d(Y){pd}(Y)<{d}(Y) and ∣Y∣=Δ(Y)|Y| = \Delta(Y), moreover the following three statements are equiconsistent: (i) There is a singular cardinal λ\lambda with pp(λ)>λ+pp(\lambda)>\lambda^+, i.e. Shelah's Strong Hypothesis fails; (ii) there is a 0-dimensional Hausdorff space XX such that ∣X∣=Δ(X)|X|=\Delta(X) is a regular cardinal and pd(X)<d(X){pd}(X)<{d}(X); (iii) there is a topological space XX such that ∣X∣=Δ(X)|X|=\Delta(X) is a regular cardinal and pd(X)<d(X){pd}(X)<{d}(X). We also prove that ∙\bullet d(X)=pd(X){d}(X)={pd}(X) for any locally compact Hausdorff space XX; ∙\bullet for every Hausdorff space XX we have ∣XâˆŁâ‰€22pd(X)|X|\le 2^{2^{{pd}(X)}} and pd(X)<d(X){pd}(X)<{d}(X) implies Δ(X)<22pd(X)\Delta(X)< 2^{2^{{pd}(X)}}; ∙\bullet for every regular space XX we have min⁥{Δ(X), w(X)}≀2pd(X) \min\{\Delta(X),\, w(X)\}\le 2^{{pd}(X)}\, and d(X)<2pd(X), {d}(X)<2^{{pd}(X)},\, moreover pd(X)<d(X){pd}(X)<{d}(X) implies  Δ(X)<2pd(X)\,\Delta(X)< {2^{{pd}(X)}}

    Coloring Cantor sets and resolvability of pseudocompact spaces

    Get PDF
    Let us denote by Ί(λ,ÎŒ)\Phi(\lambda,\mu) the statement that B(λ)=D(λ)ω\mathbb{B}(\lambda) = D(\lambda)^\omega, i.e. the Baire space of weight λ\lambda, has a coloring with ÎŒ\mu colors such that every homeomorphic copy of the Cantor set C\mathbb{C} in B(λ)\mathbb{B}(\lambda) picks up all the ÎŒ\mu colors. We call a space X X\, {\em π\pi-regular} if it is Hausdorff and for every non-empty open set UU in XX there is a non-empty open set VV such that V‟⊂U\overline{V} \subset U. We recall that a space XX is called {\em feebly compact} if every locally finite collection of open sets in XX is finite. A Tychonov space is pseudocompact iff it is feebly compact. The main result of this paper is the following. Theorem. Let XX be a crowded feebly compact π\pi-regular space and ÎŒ\mu be a fixed (finite or infinite) cardinal. If Ί(λ,ÎŒ)\Phi(\lambda,\mu) holds for all λ<c^(X)\lambda < \widehat{c}(X) then XX is ÎŒ\mu-resolvable, i.e. contains ÎŒ\mu pairwise disjoint dense subsets. (Here c^(X)\widehat{c}(X) is the smallest cardinal Îș\kappa such that XX does not contain Îș\kappa many pairwise disjoint open sets.) This significantly improves earlier results of van Mill , resp. Ortiz-Castillo and Tomita.Comment: 8 page

    Anti-Urysohn spaces

    Get PDF
    All spaces are assumed to be infinite Hausdorff spaces. We call a space "anti-Urysohn" ((AU in short)) iff any two non-emty regular closed sets in it intersect. We prove that ∙\bullet for every infinite cardinal Îș{\kappa} there is a space of size Îș{\kappa} in which fewer than cf(Îș)cf({\kappa}) many non-empty regular closed sets always intersect; ∙\bullet there is a locally countable AU space of size Îș\kappa iff ω≀Îș≀2c\omega \le \kappa \le 2^{\mathfrak c}. A space with at least two non-isolated points is called "strongly anti-Urysohn" ((SAU in short)) iff any two infinite closed sets in it intersect. We prove that ∙\bullet if XX is any SAU space then sâ‰€âˆŁXâˆŁâ‰€22c \mathfrak s\le |X|\le 2^{2^{\mathfrak c}}; ∙\bullet if r=c\mathfrak r=\mathfrak c then there is a separable, crowded, locally countable, SAU space of cardinality c\mathfrak c; \item if λ>ω\lambda > \omega Cohen reals are added to any ground model then in the extension there are SAU spaces of size Îș\kappa for all Îș∈[ω1,λ]\kappa \in [\omega_1,\lambda]; ∙\bullet if GCH holds and Îș≀λ\kappa \le\lambda are uncountable regular cardinals then in some CCC generic extension we have s=Îș\mathfrak s={\kappa},  c=λ\,\mathfrak c={\lambda}, and for every cardinal Ό∈[s,c]{\mu}\in [\mathfrak s, \mathfrak c] there is an SAU space of cardinality ÎŒ{\mu}. The questions if SAU spaces exist in ZFC or if SAU spaces of cardinality >c> \mathfrak c can exist remain open

    What causes asymmetric price transmission in agro-food sector? : meta-analysis perspective

    Get PDF
    There now exists a large literature on price transmission in agro-food sectors. However, a great majority of empirical studies focus on the existence of asymmetry and, by and large, do not allow investigating the reason for its presence or absence. This is in sharp contrast to the theoretical literature that provides a number of explanations for why we should expect (a)symmetry. In response to this, this paper tries to uncover the reasons for asymmetric price transmission in the agro-food chain. To do so, we use meta-analysis drawing on the existing studies from this area. Our focus is on the organizational and institutional characteristics of the agro-food supply chain. Our findings suggest that asymmetric price transmission in farm-retail relationship is more likely to occur in sectors/countries with more fragmented farm structure, higher governmental support and more restrictive regulations on price controls in retail sector. On the other hand, more restrictive regulations on entry barriers in retail sector and relative importance of the sector in question tend to promote symmetric farm-retail price transmission. The latter is also more likely in the presence of strong processing industry

    Az RPA kezelƑk kĂ©pzĂ©sĂ©nek fejlesztĂ©si lehetƑsĂ©gei

    Get PDF

    MezƑgazdasági árak = Agricultural Prices

    Get PDF
    Jelen kutatĂĄs azt vizsgĂĄlja, megfigyelhetƑ-e a piaci erƑ alkalmazĂĄsa a magyar sertĂ©shĂșs szektorban. A kutatĂĄs hiĂĄnypĂłtlĂł, mivel ellentĂ©tben az eddigi kutatĂĄsokkal, ahol jellemzƑen ĂĄltalĂĄnos Ă©s nem-teljes ĂĄrtranszmissziĂłs modelleket becsĂŒltek, jelen kutatĂĄsban egy strukturĂĄlis piaci modellt vezetĂŒnk le, majd becsĂŒlĂŒnk meg. Az elemzĂ©st, a termĂ©k vertikum elsƑ lĂ©pcsƑjĂ©n, a vĂĄgĂĄsra szĂĄnt Ă©lƑ sertĂ©sek keresletĂ©nek Ă©s kĂ­nĂĄlatĂĄnak szintjĂ©n vĂ©geztĂŒk. A kutatĂĄs legfontosabb eredmĂ©nye, hogy ezen a szinten nem mutathatĂł ki a piaci erƑ alkalmazĂĄsa. Ezt az elsƑ lĂĄtĂĄsra meglepƑ eredmĂ©nyt a magyar sertĂ©s tenyĂ©sztĂ©s, vĂĄgĂĄs Ă©s feldolgozĂĄs strukturĂĄlis tulajdonsĂĄgainak az elmĂ©leti vizsgĂĄlata is megerƑsĂ­tette. MegjegyzendƑ, hogy a sertĂ©svertikumnak csupĂĄn az elsƑ szintjĂ©t elemeztĂŒk. Annak ellenĂ©re, hogy ezen a szinten nem mutattuk ki, a piaci erƑ jelen lehet a tovĂĄbbi piaci szinteken. A szupermarket lĂĄncok növekvƑ fontossĂĄga Ă©s piaci rĂ©szesedĂ©se, valamint a kiskereskedelemben megnyĂ­lvĂĄnulĂł gyors koncentrĂĄciĂłs folyamat a piaci erƑ kiskereskedelemben valĂł jelenlĂ©tĂ©re utalhat. | This study investigates the existence of market power in the Hungarian pork chain. Doing this, it contributes to filling a gap in the literature. Contrary to many other studies, not an incomplete price transmission model but a structural market model is derived and estimated. The analysis is restricted to the demand and supply of pigs and thus the first stage of the Pork chain. The hypothesis of market power had to be rejected. The lack of market power result is also emphasised by the theoretical inspection and description of the structural characteristics of pork production, slaughtering and processing. Furthermore, only a small part of the total chain was analyzed. The lack of evidence on market power in the first stage, does not imply that market power is absent in downstream sectors as well. The growing importance of supermarket chains, and the rapid concentration processes in retailing suggest that market power might be present in retailing
    • 

    corecore