30,008 research outputs found

    Some Bounds for the Number of Blocks III

    Full text link
    Let D=(Ω,B)\mathcal D=(\Omega, \mathcal B) be a pair of vv point set Ω\Omega and a set B\mathcal B consists of kk point subsets of Ω\Omega which are called blocks. Let dd be the maximal cardinality of the intersections between the distinct two blocks in B\mathcal B. The triple (v,k,d)(v,k,d) is called the parameter of B\mathcal B. Let bb be the number of the blocks in B\mathcal B. It is shown that inequality (vd+2i1)b{(kd+2i1)+(kd+2i2)(vk1)+....{v\choose d+2i-1}\geq b\{{k\choose d+2i-1} +{k\choose d+2i-2}{v-k\choose 1}+.... .+(kd+i)(vki1)}.+{k\choose d+i}{v-k\choose i-1} \} holds for each ii satisfying 1ikd1\leq i\leq k-d, in the paper: Some Bounds for the Number of Blocks, Europ. J. Combinatorics 22 (2001), 91--94, by R. Noda. If bb achieves the upper bound, D\mathcal D is called a β(i)\beta(i) design. In the paper, an upper bound and a lower bound, (d+2i)(kd)iv(d+2(i1))(kd)i1 \frac{(d+2i)(k-d)}{i}\leq v \leq \frac{(d+2(i-1))(k-d)}{i-1} , for vv of a β(i)\beta(i) design D\mathcal D are given. In the present paper we consider the cases when vv does not achieve the upper bound or lower bound given above, and get new more strict bounds for vv respectively. We apply this bound to the problem of the perfect ee-codes in the Johnson scheme, and improve the bound given by Roos in 1983.Comment: Stylistic corrections are made. References are adde

    On the number of blocks required to access the core

    Get PDF
    For any transferable utility game in coalitional form with nonempty core, we show that that the number of blocks required to switch from an imputation out of the core to an imputation in the core is less than or equal to n(n-1)/2, where n is the cardinality of the player set. This number considerably improves the upper bounds found so far by Koczy (2006) and Yang (2010). Our result relies on an altered version of the procedure proposed by Sengupta and Sengupta (1996). The use of the Davis-Maschler reduced-games is also pointed out.Core; excess function; dominance path; Davis-Maschler reduced-game

    The Core Can Be Accessed with a Bounded Number of Blocks

    Get PDF
    We show the existence of an upper bound for the number of blocks required to get from one imputation to another provided that accessibility holds. The bound depends only on the number of players in the TU game considered. For the class of games with non-empty cores this means that the core can be reached via a bounded sequence of blocks.core, indirect dominance

    The Core Can Be Accessed with a Bounded Number of Blocks

    Get PDF
    We show the existence of an upper bound for the number of blocks required to get from one imputation to another provided that accessibility holds. The bound depends only on the number of players in the TU game considered. For the class of games with non-empty cores this means that the core can be reached via a bounded sequence of blocks.mathematical economics;

    On the number of blocks required to access the coalition structure core

    Get PDF
    This article shows that, for any transferable utility game in coalitional form with nonempty coalition structure core, the number of steps required to switch from a payoff configuration out of the coalition structure core to a payoff configuration in the coalition structure core is less than or equal to (n*n+4n)/4, where n is the cardinality of the player set. This number considerably improves the upper bound found so far by Koczy and Lauwers (2004).coalition structure core; excess function; payoff configuration; outsider independent domination.

    Constrained exchangeable partitions

    Full text link
    For a class of random partitions of an infinite set a de Finetti-type representation is derived, and in one special case a central limit theorem for the number of blocks is shown

    Deviations from the mean field predictions for the phase behaviour of random copolymers melts

    Full text link
    We investigate the phase behaviour of random copolymers melts via large scale Monte Carlo simulations. We observe macrophase separation into A and B--rich phases as predicted by mean field theory only for systems with a very large correlation lambda of blocks along the polymer chains, far away from the Lifshitz point. For smaller values of lambda, we find that a locally segregated, disordered microemulsion--like structure gradually forms as the temperature decreases. As we increase the number of blocks in the polymers, the region of macrophase separation further shrinks. The results of our Monte Carlo simulation are in agreement with a Ginzburg criterium, which suggests that mean field theory becomes worse as the number of blocks in polymers increases.Comment: 6 pages, 4 figures, Late
    corecore