535 research outputs found

    "The Look of Stagniation: Romania's Erratic Transition"

    Get PDF
    A transition path is expected to lead, eventually, to economic performance and sectoral structure typical of market economies. This twofold result would issue from a complex resource re-allocation process, almost automatically igniting a new mechanism of accumulation and growth. Romania's experience of persistent fluctuations around a descending trend, however, seems to contradict such notion of the one-way, self-fuelling path. It causes us to rethink some of the analytical tools and theories economists are using everyday. In this paper, I will offer the reflections of an academician together with, hopefully, some more practical suggestions. My main point is that an analysis focusing solely upon resource re-allocation mechanisms cannot fully account for Romania's erratic transition because it tends to miss the link with the dual processes of accumulation and creation of new resources. I will, therefore, reconstruct the "other side" of Romania's story by looking at its dynamic structure, described by the distribution of the economy's sectoral paths. The evolution over time of such distribution is the key to understanding the two issues of macroeconomic vulnerability and the non-sustainability of the country's current situation. Thus, the dynamics of Romania's economy is treated as a specimen of an independent variety of transition. It is one that not only proves unable to initialise and then sustain long-term growth; it seems to actually absorb and destroy more resources than it creates, in this way generating a slow agony from time to time interrupted sudden bursts of activity. The term dynamic trap is meant to describe such a repeating pattern of wild fluctuations around a contracting trend. Due partly to the short time horizon and data availability, the conclusions of the foregoing analysis can only be tentative. Still, they clearly point out the need to re-consider policy for Romania and similar countries. In particular, measures are required to put in place and to enhance mechanisms of technology transfers, to re-orient sectoral composition that generates trade specialization, and generally to create conditions for an accelerated process of accumulation of physical as well as human capital assets. The economic environment in such countries seems unable to process macroeconomic policies in the expected way.

    Pathologic Hematopoiesis: Congenital dyserythropoietic anemia Type II, congenital erythrocytosis anf thrombocytopenias

    Get PDF
    The blood contains several different types of cells. Each of these cell types is quite distinct in appearance, and each has a specific biological function. Despite their extreme structural and functional differences, blood cells are the progeny of a single type of cell: the hematopoietic stem cell (HSC). The processes involved in the production of the various cell types of the blood from the HSCs are collectively called hematopoiesis. Hematopoiesis includes HSC self-renewal, HSC commitment to specific lineages, and maturation of lineage-committed progenitors into functional blood cells. Self-renewal may occur by symmetric HSC division, such as expansion of the HSC pool during fetal life or post-HSC transplantation. Other possible fates of HSC divisions include apoptosis or mobilization to the peripheral circulation following stress such as growth factor stimulation or depletion of marrow cells by irradiation or chemotherapy. During normal steady state conditions, HSCs reside mainly in the marrow cavity, but under certain stress conditions HSCs can migrate and colonize other organs like liver and spleen in a process termed extramedullary hematopoiesis. Hematopoiesis begins early during embryogenesis and undergoes many changes during fetal and neonatal development. Unlike some organ systems that form in early life and are not continually replaced, turnover and replenishment of the hematopoietic system continue throughout life

    Analysis and comparison of microscopic traffic flow models with real traffic microscopic data

    Get PDF
    The ever more widespread use of microscopic traffic simulation in the analysis of road systems has re-focussed attention on sub-models, including car-following models. The difficulties of micro-simulation models in accurately reproducing real traffic phenomena stem not only from the complexity of calibration and validation operations but also from the structural inadequacy of the sub-models themselves. These drawbacks both originate in the scant information available on real phenomena, due to the difficulty of gathering accurate field data. In this study, the use of K-dGPS instruments allowed trajectories of four vehicles in a platoon to be accurately monitored in real traffic conditions, both on urban and extra-urban roads. Some of these data were used to analyse the behaviour of four microscopic traffic flow models which differed greatly both in approach and complexity. The effect on model calibration results of the choice of performance measures was first investigated and inter-vehicle spacing was shown to be the most reliable measure. Model calibrations showed results similar to those obtained in other studies that used test track data. Instead, validations resulted in higher deviations compared to previous studies (with peaks in cross-validations between urban and extra-urban experiments). This confirms the need for real traffic data. On comparison, all the models showed similar performances (i.e. similar deviations in validation). However, if surprisingly the simplest model performed on average better than the others, the most complex one was the most robust, never reaching particularly high deviations

    Dynamic Complementarities, Efficiency and Nash Equilibria for Populations of Firms and Workers

    Get PDF
    We consider an economy with two types of firms (innovative and non-innovative) and two types of workers (skilled and unskilled), where workers' decisions are driven by imitative behavior, and thus the evolution of such an economy depends on the initial distribution of the firms. We show that there exists a continuous of high level steady states and only one low level and asymptotically stable equilibrium. There exists a threshold value on the initial number of firms to be overcome it to located in the basin of attraction of one of the high level equilibrium. We show that in each high level equilibrium there coexists a share of innovative firms with a share of non-innovative firms, and a share of skilled workers (human capital) coexisting with a share of unskilled workers. But if the initial share of innovative firms is lower than the threshold value, then the economy evolves to a low level equilibrium wholly composed by non-innovative firms and unskilled workers. Finally, we characterise the equilibria as the evolutionarily stable strategies against a field.Imitative Behavior, Poverty Traps, Strategic Complementarities, Two Population Normal Form Game, Threshold Value.

    On the asymptotic behaviour of solutions to the fractional porous medium equation with variable density

    Get PDF
    We are concerned with the long time behaviour of solutions to the fractional porous medium equation with a variable spatial density. We prove that if the density decays slowly at infinity, then the solution approaches the Barenblatt-type solution of a proper singular fractional problem. If, on the contrary, the density decays rapidly at infinity, we show that the minimal solution multiplied by a suitable power of the time variable converges to the minimal solution of a certain fractional sublinear elliptic equation.Comment: To appear in DCDS-

    Blow-up versus global existence of solutions for reaction-diffusion equations on classes of Riemannian manifolds

    Get PDF
    It is well known from the work of Bandle et al. (J Differ Equ 251:2143-2163, 2011) that the Fujita phenomenon for reaction-diffusion evolution equations with power nonlinearities does not occur on the hyperbolic space H-N, thus marking a striking difference with the Euclidean situation. We show that, on classes of manifolds in which the bottom lambda of the L-2 spectrum of -delta is strictly positive (the hyperbolic space being thus included), a different version of the Fujita phenomenon occurs for other kinds of nonlinearities, in which the role of the critical Fujita exponent in the Euclidean case is taken by lambda. Such nonlinearities are time-independent, in contrast to the ones studied in Bandle et al. (2011). As a consequence of our results we show that, on a class of manifolds much larger than the case M = H-N considered in Bandle et al. (2011), solutions to (1.1) with power nonlinearity f(u) = u(p), p > 1, and corresponding to sufficiently small data, are global in time. Though qualitative similarities with similar problems in bounded, Euclidean domains can be seen in the results, the methods are significantly different because of noncompact setting dealt with

    Global existence for reaction-diffusion evolution equations driven by the p-Laplacian on manifolds

    Get PDF
    We consider reaction-diffusion equations driven by the p-Laplacian on noncompact, infinite volume manifolds assumed to support the Sobolev inequality and, in some cases, to have L2 spectrum bounded away from zero, the main example we have in mind being the hyperbolic space of any dimension. It is shown that, under appropriate conditions on the parameters involved and smallness conditions on the initial data, global in time solutions exist and suitable smoothing effects, namely explicit bounds on the L∞ norm of solutions at all positive times, in terms of Lq norms of the data. The geometric setting discussed here requires significant modifications w.r.t. the Euclidean strategies

    The Kuznets curve of the rich

    Get PDF
    A long-standing interest in the relationship between inequality and sustainable growth continues to fascinate economists among other social scientists. It must be noted, however, that most empirical efforts have focussed on the income inequality–growth nexus, while studies on wealth inequality are much scarcer. This study attempts to fill such a gap in the literature by assessing the correspondence between the top 1 percent's wealth share and economic growth. Employing time series cointegration techniques, we study the experience of France and the United States from 1950 to 2014. Our estimates suggest that the output growth rate is an inverted-U-shaped function of the wealth share of the top 1 percent. The estimated relationship is robust to variations in control variables and estimation methods. We compute the local optimal wealth share, understood as the share of wealth compatible with the maximum growth rate, and show that France is growing close to its long-run potential, while the United States is significantly below its
    corecore