8 research outputs found
Higher education, employersâ monopsony power and the labour share in OECD countries
This paper examines the impact of higher education on the labour share. It is based on the following idea: as education offers adaptability skills, it should reduce employersâ monopsony power and, therefore, increase the labour share. This idea is developed in a two-sector model with search unemployment and wage competition between employers to attract/keep workers. Using panel data for eleven OECD countries, we show that the proportion of higher educated in the population has a significant positive effect on the labour share: typically, an increase of one standard deviation in higher education induces a three point increase in the labour share. The other determinants of the labour share are compatible with the theoretical model. They include the capital-output ratio (-), minimum to median wage ratio (+), union density (+). We also find that the unemployment rate has a negative and significant impact on the labour share, which, together with the positive impact of higher education, is incompatible with a three-factor model where factors are paid their marginal products.Search frictions; Adaptability; Labour share; Macroeconomic panel data
Higher education, employersâ monopsony power and the labour share in OECD countries
This paper examines the impact of higher education on the labour share. It is based on the following idea: as education offers adaptability skills, it should reduce employersâ monopsony power and, therefore, increase the labour share. This idea is developed in a two-sector model with search unemployment and wage competition between employers to attract/keep workers. Using panel data for eleven OECD countries, we show that the proportion of higher educated in the population has a significant positive effect on the labour share: typically, an increase of one standard deviation in higher education induces a three point increase in the labour share. The other determinants of the
labour share are compatible with the theoretical model. They include the capital-output ratio (-), minimum to median wage ratio (+), union density (+). We also find that the unemployment rate has a negative and significant impact on the labour share, which, together with the positive impact of higher education, is incompatible with a three-factor model where factors are paid their marginal products
Impact of income redistribution on middle class households: A cross-country comparison based on the LIS data
In the context of economic and financial difficulties, the debate over the effect of income taxation and redistribution has come back in most of the European countries. In this paper, we use the LIS data to examine the impact of income redistribution on middle class households from a cross-country perspective. To this aim, we calculate the balance between, on the one hand, the taxes and social contributions those households have to pay and, on the other, what they receive as social transfers. The research question here is whether middle class households benefit more or less from income redistribution than lower and upper class households. According to this study, income redistribution schemes appear to be "redistributive" in most of the European countries, which means that households having high income contribute to the income of those having lower resources. However, the intensity of the redistribution varies from one country to another: basically, northern European countries, in line with the Beveridge "universal" approach are more redistributive than southern countries, where social protection is mainly financed by employers and employee social insurance contributions
Higher education, employers' monopsony power and the labour share in OECD countries
This paper examines the impact of higher education on the labour share. It is based on the following idea: as education offers adaptability skills, it should reduce employers' monopsony power and, therefore, increase the labour share. This idea is developed in a two-sector model with search unemployment and wage competition between employers to attract/keep workers. Using panel data for eleven OECD countries, we show that the proportion of higher educated in the population hasa significant positive effect on the labour share: typically, an increase of one standard deviation inhigher education induces a three point increase in the labour share. The other determinants of the labour share are compatible with the theoretical model. They include the capital-output ratio (-), minimum to median wage ratio (+), union density (+). We also find that the unemployment rate has a negative and significant impact on the labour share, which, together with the positive impact of higher education, is incompatible with a three-factor model where factors are paid their marginal products.Search frictions; Adaptability; Labour share; Macroeconomic panel data
The personal and the factor distributions of income in a cross-section of countries
The shares of capital and labour in national income vary substantially both over time and across countries. This paper shows that the factor distribution of income is an essential determinant of the personal distribution of income. We use cross-country and panel data for a group of developed and developing countries to show that a larger labour share is associated with a lower Gini coefficient of personal incomes. This effect is not only statistically significant but also economically important. An increase in the labour share in Mexico to that observed in the US would reduce the Gini coefficient of the former by between two and five points.
Une approche de lâeffet du passage sur Internet dâune enquĂȘte en population gĂ©nĂ©rale
Pour faire suite Ă un prĂ©cĂ©dent travail de recherche et afin de gĂ©rer au mieux le passage en ligne de son enquĂȘte baromĂ©trique sur les Conditions de vie et les Aspirations, le CRĂDOC a organisĂ© la 37Ăšme vague de son dispositif d'enquĂȘte de façon simultanĂ©e et identique, sur deux Ă©chantillons distincts, l'un interrogĂ© en face-Ă -face, l'autre interrogĂ© en ligne. Sur de nombreux indicateurs, Ă©tablis aussi bien Ă partir de questions factuelles que de questions d'opinion, les deux modes de collecte Ă©tablissent des rĂ©sultats parfaitement comparables. Ces similitudes concernent des sujets aussi variĂ©s que le rapport Ă l'emploi, le logement, le cadre de vie et le sentiment de sĂ©curitĂ©, la santĂ©, le moral Ă©conomique, les opinions sur l'union ou l'adoption par des couples de mĂȘme sexe, les jugements portĂ©s sur le fonctionnement de la sociĂ©tĂ© ou les effets de la mondialisation, les opinions sur la pauvretĂ© ou le chĂŽmage, le sentiment de restriction budgĂ©taire ou la perception de l'Ă©volution de son niveau de vie. Pour nombre d'indicateurs sur ces diffĂ©rents thĂšmes, il n'y a quasiment aucune diffĂ©rence entre les deux enquĂȘtes. Le mode de collecte induit cependant des effets propres quant Ă la rĂ©alisation du terrain (durĂ©e de l'interrogation plus courte en ligne, possibilitĂ© pour un paneliste de rĂ©pondre en plusieurs fois). Il n'est pas non plus sans effet sur les caractĂ©ristiques des rĂ©pondants, chaque mode de collecte recelant ses avantages et ses inconvĂ©nients. Ainsi l'analyse du niveau de diplĂŽme montre une surreprĂ©sentation des plus diplĂŽmĂ©s dans le panel online. Sur le critĂšre de la taille du mĂ©nage ou encore sur le taux de propriĂ©taires, les donnĂ©es issues de l'enquĂȘte en ligne sont, en revanche, plus proches de la rĂ©alitĂ© que les donnĂ©es issues de l'enquĂȘte en face-Ă -face. Enfin, les informations relatives aux revenus sont de moins bonne qualitĂ© dans l'enquĂȘte en ligne. Il est trĂšs difficile d'y exploiter la structure des revenus (par type de revenus ou par personne du foyer qui les perçoit) et, trĂšs souvent, on doit se contenter de la position donnĂ©e dans une Ă©chelle pour les revenus globaux de l'ensemble du foyer. Dans le mĂȘme temps, le niveau de vie mĂ©dian est plus Ă©levĂ© dans l'enquĂȘte en ligne (1 800 euros, + 20% par rapport Ă l'enquĂȘte en face-Ă -face). Au final, sur les questions gĂ©nĂ©ralistes du questionnaire (hors questions insĂ©rĂ©es par des clients et donc confidentielles), on mesure un Ă©cart moyen de l'ordre de 4 points par modalitĂ© de rĂ©ponse entre les deux Ă©chantillons. Cet Ă©cart moyen, dĂ©clinĂ© par grands blocs thĂ©matiques (comprenant chacun de 9 Ă 17 questions), varie (en valeur absolue) de 1,6 points pour la situation d'emploi Ă 7,7 points pour les TIC