104,238 research outputs found

    The capture time of grids

    Get PDF
    We consider the game of Cops and Robber played on the Cartesian product of two trees. Assuming the players play perfectly, it is shown that if there are two cops in the game, then the length of the game (known as the 2-capture time of the graph) is equal to half the diameter of the graph. In particular, the 2-capture time of the m x n grid is proved to be floor ((m+n-2)/2).Comment: 7 page

    On a Bounded Budget Network Creation Game

    Full text link
    We consider a network creation game in which each player (vertex) has a fixed budget to establish links to other players. In our model, each link has unit price and each agent tries to minimize its cost, which is either its local diameter or its total distance to other players in the (undirected) underlying graph of the created network. Two versions of the game are studied: in the MAX version, the cost incurred to a vertex is the maximum distance between the vertex and other vertices, and in the SUM version, the cost incurred to a vertex is the sum of distances between the vertex and other vertices. We prove that in both versions pure Nash equilibria exist, but the problem of finding the best response of a vertex is NP-hard. We take the social cost of the created network to be its diameter, and next we study the maximum possible diameter of an equilibrium graph with n vertices in various cases. When the sum of players' budgets is n-1, the equilibrium graphs are always trees, and we prove that their maximum diameter is Theta(n) and Theta(log n) in MAX and SUM versions, respectively. When each vertex has unit budget (i.e. can establish link to just one vertex), the diameter of any equilibrium graph in either version is Theta(1). We give examples of equilibrium graphs in the MAX version, such that all vertices have positive budgets and yet the diameter is Omega(sqrt(log n)). This interesting (and perhaps counter-intuitive) result shows that increasing the budgets may increase the diameter of equilibrium graphs and hence deteriorate the network structure. Then we prove that every equilibrium graph in the SUM version has diameter 2^O(sqrt(log n)). Finally, we show that if the budget of each player is at least k, then every equilibrium graph in the SUM version is k-connected or has diameter smaller than 4.Comment: 28 pages, 3 figures, preliminary version appeared in SPAA'1

    The domination game played on diameter 2 graphs

    Get PDF
    Let Îłg(G)\gamma_g(G) be the game domination number of a graph GG. It is proved that if diam(G)=2{\rm diam}(G) = 2, then Îłg(G)≀⌈n(G)2⌉−⌊n(G)11⌋\gamma_g(G) \le \left\lceil \frac{n(G)}{2} \right\rceil- \left\lfloor \frac{n(G)}{11}\right\rfloor. The bound is attained: if diam(G)=2{\rm diam}(G) = 2 and n(G)≀10n(G) \le 10, then Îłg(G)=⌈n(G)2⌉\gamma_g(G) = \left\lceil \frac{n(G)}{2} \right\rceil if and only if GG is one of seven sporadic graphs with n(G)≀6n(G)\le 6 or the Petersen graph, and there are exactly ten graphs of diameter 22 and order 1111 that attain the bound

    Localization game on geometric and planar graphs

    Get PDF
    The main topic of this paper is motivated by a localization problem in cellular networks. Given a graph GG we want to localize a walking agent by checking his distance to as few vertices as possible. The model we introduce is based on a pursuit graph game that resembles the famous Cops and Robbers game. It can be considered as a game theoretic variant of the \emph{metric dimension} of a graph. We provide upper bounds on the related graph invariant ζ(G)\zeta (G), defined as the least number of cops needed to localize the robber on a graph GG, for several classes of graphs (trees, bipartite graphs, etc). Our main result is that, surprisingly, there exists planar graphs of treewidth 22 and unbounded ζ(G)\zeta (G). On a positive side, we prove that ζ(G)\zeta (G) is bounded by the pathwidth of GG. We then show that the algorithmic problem of determining ζ(G)\zeta (G) is NP-hard in graphs with diameter at most 22. Finally, we show that at most one cop can approximate (arbitrary close) the location of the robber in the Euclidean plane

    Subgraphs and Colourability of Locatable Graphs

    Full text link
    We study a game of pursuit and evasion introduced by Seager in 2012, in which a cop searches the robber from outside the graph, using distance queries. A graph on which the cop wins is called locatable. In her original paper, Seager asked whether there exists a characterisation of the graph property of locatable graphs by either forbidden or forbidden induced subgraphs, both of which we answer in the negative. We then proceed to show that such a characterisation does exist for graphs of diameter at most 2, stating it explicitly, and note that this is not true for higher diameter. Exploring a different direction of topic, we also start research in the direction of colourability of locatable graphs, we also show that every locatable graph is 4-colourable, but not necessarily 3-colourable.Comment: 25 page

    Cops and Robbers on diameter two graphs

    Full text link
    In this short paper we study the game of Cops and Robbers, played on the vertices of some fixed graph GG of order nn. The minimum number of cops required to capture a robber is called the cop number of GG. We show that the cop number of graphs of diameter 2 is at most 2n\sqrt{2n}, improving a recent result of Lu and Peng by a constant factor. We conjecture that this bound is still not optimal, and obtain some partial results towards the optimal bound.Comment: 5 page
    • 

    corecore