13 research outputs found
Grass, money, and cattle: The livestock dealers of Phalaborwa
African Studies Seminar series. Paper presented 8 May 1995During my visits to the Lowveld, I have not come across any veal
monsters or their animal loving enemies. I guess one would have to go
to the British port of Dover to witness that particular cattle battle. In
the same way, the ecologists1 and environmentalists' campaign against
the hamburgers that threaten the Amazon rain forest is best
understood from an American point of view. Phalaborwa is not veal or
hamburger country, but the people love their meat and even named the
township of Namakgale after it. Whether the people of Phalaborwa
love their cattle is more dificult to say, but they do own and keep them.
There are, however, a few questions about who should raise cattle and
for what purposes that are yet to be answered to everybody's
satisfaction. Everybody in this case being government officials
implementing development, White ranchers producing meat for the
country, and Black elites wanting a share of the beef business, as well
as poor villagers who wish to speculate and accumulate using livestock
as a concentrator of value. The idea that some people are not qualified
to keep livestock is what constitutes the local cattle battle.
During one of my interviews with farmers in Phalaborwa a White beef
baron, whom we shall call Willem Botha, told me that
Blacks have a misconception that grass, money, and cattle are one and
the same thing. In 1982 the drought killed 147,000 and the 1992 -
80,000 cattle in Giyani but the owners got nothing because they refused
to sell. (2) This is an old problem in the business of modernization. Blacks, or
peasants, or tribals, as the case may be, are accused not merely of
understanding modern business differently, but of just not
understanding. Despite the efforts of many scholars to show that such
behaviour is not irrational, the dominant culture of the civil service, the
development agencies and the educated elites, tend to see only
problems with ‘traditional’ behaviour. For instance: an anthropologist
from Botswana who, in a recent book, compared White ranchers to Black
entrepreneurs and wrote in relation to one of the village farmers:
By contrast, the better-experienced settler ranchers expanded their
land as a single unit (cf Vorster and the Clarks). Most probably,
however, Tau was inspired by the African mentality which finds
greatness, not in the amount of land or size of the ranch but rather in
the quantity of farms, notwithstanding their sizes. In his home village,
people used to talk of him as the man with two Tuli Block farms. Among
settlers, the reverse is true; grandeur is based on the size of a ranch and
not necessarily on the quantity of farms. Mazonde: 1993,90
According to Mazonde, Tau's African mentality, more than his lack of
access to information or his inexperience explain his failure to acquire a
large farm with a river frontage or direct road link and his failure to
ensure that when he bought his second farm it was adjacent to his first
one. It is this same perceived African mentality that may be used to
explain why Willem Botha suggested to me that,
Village elders are children in matters of modern economy and must
therefore be guided (by the state). Why, they are even bartering as if
they are not in a money economy! They barter their big bullocks for
scrap heifers from White dealers who exploit their lack of
understanding of weights and the market. The African mentality somehow prevents people from seeing that one large farm is easier to manage than two small ones that are situated several miles apart, or that bullocks fetch higher prices than heifers on the market. Contrary to Willem Botha's view, barter is not a pre-capitalist mode of exchange though it may appear as such when taken
out of its social context. (C. Humphrey and S. Hugh-Jones eds. 1992)
There are numerous examples of counter trade between countries and
barter between traders which fit into the modern economy perfectly.
During my visits to the Lowveld, I have not come across any veal
monsters or their animal loving enemies. I guess one would have to go
to the British port of Dover to witness that particular cattle battle. In
the same way, the ecologists1 and environmentalists' campaign against
the hamburgers that threaten the Amazon rain forest is best
understood from an American point of view. Phalaborwa is not veal or
hamburger country, but the people love their meat and even named the
township of Namakgale after it. Whether the people of Phalaborwa
love their cattle is more dificult to say, but they do own and keep them.
There are, however, a few questions about who should raise cattle and
for what purposes that are yet to be answered to everybody's
satisfaction. Everybody in this case being government officials
implementing development, White ranchers producing meat for the
country, and Black elites wanting a share of the beef business, as well
as poor villagers who wish to speculate and accumulate using livestock
as a concentrator of value. The idea that some people are not qualified
to keep livestock is what constitutes the local cattle battle.
During one of my interviews with farmers in Phalaborwa a White beef
baron, whom we shall call Willem Botha, told me that
Blacks have a misconception that grass, money, and cattle are one and
the same thing. In 1982 the drought killed 147,000 and the 1992 -
80,000 cattle in Giyani but the owners got nothing because they refused
to sell. (2) This is an old problem in the business of modernization. Blacks, or
peasants, or tribals, as the case may be, are accused not merely of
understanding modern business differently, but of just not
understanding. Despite the efforts of many scholars to show that such
behaviour is not irrational, the dominant culture of the civil service, the
development agencies and the educated elites, tend to see only
problems with ‘traditional’ behaviour. For instance: an anthropologist
from Botswana who, in a recent book, compared White ranchers to Black
entrepreneurs and wrote in relation to one of the village farmers:
By contrast, the better-experienced settler ranchers expanded their
land as a single unit (cf Vorster and the Clarks). Most probably,
however, Tau was inspired by the African mentality which finds
greatness, not in the amount of land or size of the ranch but rather in
the quantity of farms, notwithstanding their sizes. In his home village,
people used to talk of him as the man with two Tuli Block farms. Among
settlers, the reverse is true; grandeur is based on the size of a ranch and
not necessarily on the quantity of farms. Mazonde: 1993,90
According to Mazonde, Tau's African mentality, more than his lack of
access to information or his inexperience explain his failure to acquire a
large farm with a river frontage or direct road link and his failure to
ensure that when he bought his second farm it was adjacent to his first
one. It is this same perceived African mentality that may be used to
explain why Willem Botha suggested to me that,
Village elders are children in matters of modern economy and must
therefore be guided (by the state). Why, they are even bartering as if
they are not in a money economy! They barter their big bullocks for
scrap heifers from White dealers who exploit their lack of
understanding of weights and the market. The African mentality somehow prevents people from seeing that one large farm is easier to manage than two small ones that are situated several miles apart, or that bullocks fetch higher prices than heifers on the market. Contrary to Willem Botha's view, barter is not a pre-capitalist mode of exchange though it may appear as such when taken
out of its social context. (C. Humphrey and S. Hugh-Jones eds. 1992)
There are numerous examples of counter trade between countries and
barter between traders which fit into the modern economy perfectly.
Discussed out of context, both barter and the African mentality can only
appear silly. As provocative as the concept is, this paper will not engage the notion of an African mentality directly except insofar as it is used by my
informants to explain their or other people's behaviour. It needs a more
careful problematisation than I can give at present. This paper is,
however, not meant to provide a political economy of cattle in
Phalaborwa or even detailed profiles of the cattle keepers even though
I realise that this is crucial for the establishment of the social context
and it will have to be done at a later stage. My present concern is
merely to discuss some of the local ideas about cattle in the money
economy and to illustrate the problems associated with a lack of a
common vocabulary that result when a bureaucratic and technical-scientific
world view comes into contact with foreign ideas and
economic strategies
Book Reviews
Reviews of:
Death, Belief and Politics in Central African History. By Walima T. Kalusa and Megan Vaughan
Looking For Mrs Livingstone. By Julie Davidso
Book Reviews
Reviews of:
Death, Belief and Politics in Central African History. By Walima T. Kalusa and Megan Vaughan
Looking For Mrs Livingstone. By Julie Davidso
Book Reviews
Reviews of:
Death, Belief and Politics in Central African History. By Walima T. Kalusa and Megan Vaughan
Looking For Mrs Livingstone. By Julie Davidso
‘I Will Crawl Before You’ Political endorsements, defections and patronage in Zambian elections
While public endorsement of presidential candidates is a relatively new phenomenon in Zambian politics, political defections have existed for a longer period. However, both of these political manoeuvres have increasingly become ubiquitous since Zambia’s return to multiparty democracy in the 1990s. Often, defectors prey on the perceived popularity of a presidential candidate to secure lucrative government positions for themselves and their kin. Defections demonstrate that Zambian politicians, at all levels, have weak ties of loyalty or ideological commitment to political parties. These weak ties result in vertical mobility of defectors from a perceived weak party to one considered to have higher prospects of forming government and ‘eating’. Based on a critical case study of the January 2015 presidential by-election, this paper uses the well-tested concept of patronage to explain political endorsements and defections in Zambia’s Third Republic. The paper concludes that recurrent cross-party endorsements and defections undermine the consolidation of political parties and maybe even democracy itself
Refractory Frontier: Intra-party Democracy in the Zambian Polity
Despite the important role that intra-party democracy plays in democratic consolidation, particularly in third-wave democracies, it has not received as much attention as inter-party democracy. Based on the Zambian polity, this article uses the concept of selectocracy to explain why, to a large extent, intra-party democracy has remained a refractory frontier. Two traits of intra-party democracy are examined: leadership transitions at party president-level and the selection of political party members for key leadership positions. The present study of four political parties: United National Independence Party (UNIP), Movement for Multiparty Democracy (MMD), United Party for National Development (UPND) and Patriotic Front (PF) demonstrates that the iron law of oligarchy predominates leadership transitions and selection. Within this milieu, intertwined but fluid factors, inimical to democratic consolidation but underpinning selectocracy, are explained
Book Reviews
Reviews of:
Death, Belief and Politics in Central African History. By Walima T. Kalusa and Megan Vaughan
Looking For Mrs Livingstone. By Julie Davidso