1,731 research outputs found

    Economic Growth and Financial Depth: Is the Relationship Extinct Already?

    Get PDF
    finance-growth nexus, rolling regression, robustness, cross-country growth

    À propos de la pseudo-union monĂ©taire anglo-irlandaise

    Get PDF

    Un modĂšle de l’offre de travail des bĂ©nĂ©ficiaires de l’aide sociale au QuĂ©bec

    Get PDF
    Cet article présente la stratégie de recherche d'un projet qui vise à analyser le comportement des bénéficiaires de l'aide sociale concernant leurs activités de travail et de prospection d'emploi, afin de mieux connaßtre les déterminants de leurs plans d'offre de travailThis paper presents a labor supply model of the low-incomes individuals which will be applied to data collected by a survey of the population on welfare in Québec during 1976. The model specifies the variables which determine the subjective wage rate as an indicator of the incentive to work. This equation of the subjective wage rate is the structural form of the model while a labor supply equation and a market wage rate equation constitute the reduced form. The amount of labor supplied is thus a function of the cost of job search, the length of the search period, the net wage rate, the individual amount of rationing in the labor market, autonomous income etc.. The exact econometric specification of the model will be presented when the results of the estimation will be communicated

    De QuĂ©bec inc. Ă  QuĂ©bec int’l

    Get PDF

    L’incidence de la rente publique sur l’épargne privĂ©e : un survol de la littĂ©rature thĂ©orique et empirique

    Get PDF
    This paper provides a survey of the literature on the effect of public pension funds on private savings. Both theoretical and empirical studies are discussed within a simple theoretical frame-work. The survey concludes that private saving is probably negatively influenced by public pension funds but that the magnitude of the effect is uncertain

    Why Banning Embedded Sales Commissions Is a Public Policy Issue

    Get PDF
    Regulatory authorities have consulted on the option of banning embedded sales commissions for Canadian financial advisors. Such an action would create more problems than it would solve. It would have serious ramifications for Canadians’ access to financial advice and raise issues of choice, industry concentration and price transparency for clients seeking advice on investments and retirement. Financial advisors have much greater knowledge of investments than their clients, who rightly expect value from their advisors’ services. Advisors may also face conflicts of interest when they make recommendations about a financial product whose manufacturer might be paying the advisor for selling its products. Banning sales commissions from the manufacturers and having the client pay the advisor directly instead brings its own problems. This is because financial advice is a good with peculiar characteristics. Firstly, financial advice has three fundamental components – the alpha, beta and gamma factors. Together, they define the roles financial advisors play: (alpha) asset or portfolio manager, (beta) asset allocator (rebalancing a client’s portfolio), and (gamma) coach with regard to savings discipline and financial planning. Financial advice has value thanks to the interplay between the three factors. Studies of the issue which have focused on one factor at a time, usually the alpha, produce results that are skewed; however, when studies measure all three factors, the evidence shows that financial advice has significant value, greater than the usual cost charged to clients. Secondly, financial advice is an “experience good”, meaning that clients don’t know ahead of time how good financial advice is until they see how it works out. Assessing the value of financial advice may take many years. Since they can’t immediately measure what they’re paying for, clients with modest incomes or wealth are usually willing only to pay low fees, or not pay at all up front. This means that banning embedded commissions would lead to a reduction in demand for advice from modest-income households. The U.K. provides an example which should not be followed. Regulators there have banned embedded commissions, forcing clients to pay directly for financial advice. The result is that modest-income clients have decided not to seek financial advice, even though that decision will likely negatively affect their portfolios. The dangers of this “advice gap” are being downplayed by those who believe that robo-advisors and banks can fill the need instead. In fact, robo-advisors and banks are mostly not equipped to step into the gamma role of coaching their clients. A ban would also mean less choice in the market for a service that needs to be competitive and innovative to serve the broad spectrum of clients’ circumstances, risk appetites and needs. In addition, smaller and independent product manufacturers and distributors would be squeezed out, creating a market concentration in the hands of the bigger players. Pricing transparency might very well be another victim of a ban as a market with significant disparities in fee levels is created. In crafting their policies, regulatory authorities should bear in mind that people need to have wide access to financial advice and to have an opportunity to become more financially literate. Keeping the market for financial services and products competitive, innovative and transparent is the path to continued success. A ban on embedded sales commissions would severely hamper these goals
    • 

    corecore