41 research outputs found

    Introducing Inventiveness into the Patent System: Submission to the Review of the National Innovation System

    Get PDF
    Because of the potential impact of the patent system on innovation diffusion, particularly on continuous and/or incremental innovation, patent policy should be of central importance to the review of the national innovation system. Substantial empirical evidence shows that most industrial innovations are not induced by the patent system. Even in very large markets, such as the USA, only a minority of patents are likely to be induced by the patent system. To the extent that patents do induce innovations, it is the inventiveness of the innovation which gives rise to possible social benefits (externalities, mainly in the form of knowledge spillovers) which may offset the costs of a patent system and thus give rise to a net economic benefit. On the basis of this evidence about the inducement effect of the patent system, and evidence on the current very low inventiveness standard for patent grant, policy proposals are put forward to re-introduce inventiveness into the patent system, thus making it potentially welfare-enhancing. These proposed changes would also have a major impact in ameliorating the negative impact of the patent system on continuous/incremental innovation

    Copyright in the digital environment

    Get PDF
    This submission briefly reviews the dearth of empirical evidence that copyright policy is either effective or efficient. It then focuses on consumer rights, how these are unnecessarily undermined by copyright policy, and how this lack of balance between producer and consumer rights is radically worsened in a digital environment with legislated monopoly privileges. A poor consumer environment will impede the development of a flourishing digital sector. A range of specific issues are discussed briefly: double-dipping through technological protection measures (TPMs), the right for communities to access cultural material sold using copyright privileges, the excessive strength of copyright privileges, compliance costs and the proportionality of penalties

    An inventive step for the patent system?

    Get PDF
    The inventive step is the critical variable in determining balance between patent costs and patent benefits. Set at the right level it ensures that the knowledge spillovers from new inventions offset the costs of restraining competition. But asking the question "is it obvious?" sets a far lower standard for patent grant than asking "is it inventive?" The author argues that for benefits to offset costs the minimum standard of inventiveness must be a contribution to new knowledge. Without such new knowledge there can be no benefits to justify the cost of the restraint on competition.Copyright Information: Author holds the copyright of the work (From author's email of 3/01/2013

    Trade treaties and patent policy: searching for a balanced approach

    No full text
    Patents were originally designed to encourage technological innovation, which would not otherwise occur, and which create spillover benefits. Careful design is needed to ensure patents do not provide windfall benefits to inventions which would take place absent patents. Further, for the grant of a patent to be economically rational the patented invention must have a reasonable probability of providing spillover (dynamic growth) benefits that exceed monopoly (static inefficiency) losses. This paper draws on the substantial empirical research on industrial innovation and how patent systems work in practice to develop a first-best set of policy parameters for a balanced (parsimonious) patent system. That is, it attempts to design a set of parameters which maximise dynamic growth benefits while minimising static efficiency losses, thus complying with TRIPS Article 7. These parameters are compared with TRIPS and with the TRIPS-Plus elements which the USA is seeking from bi-lateral and regional trade treaties. The resulting schema allows a clearer view of the cost of patent policy provisions in "trade" treaties

    The evolution of patent policy: redefining inventiveness

    No full text
    Economists assume patented inventions contain new knowledge which creates the spillover benefits providing dynamic efficiency gains to offset the static efficiency losses of the monopoly grant. Unfortunately this assumption is out-of-date. A minor difference in design is now taken as sufficient inventiveness to merit a monopoly. This paper discusses the difference between economic and legal approaches to determining if an 'invention' merits a monopoly. It presents detail on the policy rules determining patent grant and investigates the legal decisions underlying these. The legal focus on whether an invention is 'obvious' - rather than whether it is 'inventive' allows courts to avoid the question of whether the 'invention' embodies any new knowledge or know-how. As a consequence the key economic principle underlying patent policy is ignored in decisions about the grant of patents for specific 'inventions'

    A question of balance

    No full text
    Because the patent system may do substantial harm as well as possible good, balance between the innovation inducement effect and the competition reduction effect has always been important. It has less often been recognised that the patent system attracts the kind of ‘gaming’ behaviour that has been rife in tax policy (Section 1). The current review of patentable subject matter provides the opportunity to return the patent system to the narrow realm in which it belongs—where there is likely to be a benefit to the public. This would be consistent with current empirical evidence—that patents are important in inducing innovation only where technology is highly codified or where the initial investment is very large compared to market size (Section 2). Establishing the boundaries of actual patent policy is challenging, but it can be assumed that the government’s intent is that the overall system not be welfare-reducing. This means that there must be a reasonable consideration in exchange for the monopoly—patent monopolies should not be lightly granted. There has never been any government decision to extend the boundaries of patentable subject matter to new fields such as software, discoveries or methods of medical treatment. These major competition and innovation policy decisions have been made within the patent administration system (Section 3). There is clearly a major gap between patent policy and the actual outcomes as delivered by the patent administration system. These gaps are explored in Section 4, where a series of legal decisions and legal doctrines are considered from an economic viewpoint. The gulf between policy and practice suggests the need for: serious attention to ‘gaming’ behaviour, including ‘anti-avoidance’ provisions and penalties for undermining the patent system; a need to redress the way in which the patent playing field is so substantially sloped in favour of the patent applicant that many uninventive ‘inventions’ are being granted patents: a need for a multi-faceted team to address the gaps between patent policy and practice to design a robust system that will operate to enhance national economic well-being and be resistant to ‘gaming’ behaviour. Besides addressing ‘gaming’ behaviour and the bias against the public interest, this could include: substantially increasing the inventiveness threshold; requiring claims clarity from the point of application/grant; and compensating losers, possibly by limiting the monopoly grant to the prevention of copying; a need for regular evaluation of the patent system overall, and of legal decisions that impact on patent policy in particular; and a need for the collection of proper economic data on the impact of the patent system, including: provision of advice to the patent office whenever a monopoly right is exercised; collection of data through the National Innovation Survey to identify the impact of patents on innocent innovators, and estimate the proportion of innovations induced by the patent system

    Empirical evidence on the inventive step

    No full text
    The height of the inventive step is critical in balancing the costs and benefits of patent systems. This empirical analysis assesses this, using the economic yardstick of how much new knowledge is required for patent grant. But examiners and courts ask a different question - is it obvious? This creates a much lower standard, reinforced by continual amendment, semantic minutiae and the suggestion doctrine for combinations. The result is that many granted patents contribute no new knowledge and therefore no benefits to offset their costs. Such a low inventive step likely impedes rather than encourages innovation

    How High is The Inventive Step? Some Empirical Evidence

    Get PDF
    The inventive step is nowadays generally regarded as the key threshold variable ensuring balance in patent systems, effectively operating as a proxy to ensure benefits exceeding costs. Despite the active debate about the current inventiveness standard, there has been little attempt to measure it. The study reported here uses data from recently granted Australian business method patents, and tests these inventions against an economic rather than a legal yardstick. The 72 cases were assessed for their contribution to knowledge or know-how—none were found. The data are organised here to throw light on the key reasons underlying the monopoly grant to these uninventive patents. The first issue addressed is whether there was a problem identifying existing knowledge. In 12 out of 69 cases no novelty or inventiveness objections were raised, either in Australia or for parallel overseas applications (USPTO or EPO). Lengthy and complex drafting contributes to the few cases where existing knowledge did not lead to inventiveness objections. The cases demonstrate that a range of procedural rules operate to allow grant of a patent monopoly to many ‘inventions’ that do not offer any advances in knowledge or know-how,and so provide no social benefits. The rules and procedures arising from the research are: · the ‘reverse onus of proof’—that the patent office has to prove obviousness, not the applicant inventiveness; · the ‘suggestion’ test for assessing combinations of existing elements; · amendment of specifications to allow narrow differences from the existing knowledge identified by examiners; · acceptance of trivial differences, sometimes simply semantic, to determine inventiveness; · failure to apply the analogous use test to processes, despite its obvious suitability for this purpose; and · policy presumptions that the solution to a trivial problem is inventive, or that ideas themselves merit monopolies. Many of the cases in the dataset have parallel overseas applications and review of the communications between applicants and examiners at the EPO and the USPTO throws light on overseas grant practices. While half the applications that have been assessed by the USPTO have been rejected, the other half have been accepted, and the procedural problems identified in Australia are also evident in the USA. The situation at the EPO is more complex,as rejection is usually based on the lack of a “technical effect”. But three very trivial software systems have been granted patents by the EPO. It is unclear how they managed to pass either the technical effect test or the inventiveness test. As it is a range of rules and procedures which have allowed the grant of these patents, it seems likely that equally trivial patents are being granted in other fields of technology

    Understanding innovative firms: an exploration of the use of USPTO data to identify innovative firms in small and medium sized economies

    No full text
    The limitations of using patent data as a measure of technological innovation have long been known (Griliches, 1990). Despite this, patent data are frequently used in this way, providing potentially misleading analyses for policy makers. Kingston and Scally (2006) have shown that, for countries outside the NAFTA region, USPTO small enterprise data can provide a potentially more valid means of identifying genuine innovative activity in small and medium sized economies. The Kingston/Scally analysis focuses on inventors, a strategy partly forced by the available USPTO data on granted patents. From the perspective of national industry and innovation policy there is at least an equal (if not greater) interest in innovative firms. This exploratory analysis investigates whether the Kingston/Scally analysis can be extended from inventors to assignee firms and considers the challenges of making this conversion. It also explores whether such a data series can be used to develop a typology of innovating firms which can be of interest for research and policy analysis purposes. The approach has been to take data for a single country - here Australia. The initial dataset extracted from the USPTO BIB series from 1969 to 2010, consists of all granted patents where any inventor reports Australia as their country of residence. From this dataset of 23,834 cases, the sub-set where the patent was assigned to any entity other than an individual was first extracted (18,797 cases). Because of the interest in developing analysis useful for industry and innovation policy, the focus here is on firms, so all 2,245 non-profit entities were then excluded. Data on the country of the assignee firm was then added to the dataset. This identified 3,912 cases where the assignee firm had no Australian residence, leaving a balance of 12,962 patents owned by assignees with at least one patent owned by an entity based in Australia. It is well known that both patent ownership and returns from patent ownership are highly skewed distributions. The 12,962 patents remaining in the dataset are owned by 3,419 firms, of which 2,256 each have only one US patent during the 42 year period covered by the data. Within the remaining 1,163 firms patent ownership is highly skewed - at one extreme 567 firms have only 2 patents each while at the other extreme one firm, Silverbrook Research Pty Ltd owns 3,666 US patents granted between 1998 and 2010. The major part of the paper identifies a typology of Australian-based firms patenting in the USA. While only a limited range of variables are available from BIB, the small entity fee data allows the identification of most firms by size; in addition data on patent classifications provide at least some indication of the technology space within which these firms are operating. The long time series (42 years) allows investigation of whether there are changes in the types of firms patenting in the USA during this period. The major analysis, however, concentrates on the last 20-25 years. Three principal groupings of firms stand out - those which patent only once; Silverbrook, with its portfolio of thousands of US patents; and the remaining 1,162 firms. Because once-off patenters dominate the dataset, it is relevant to ask some questions about these firms - are they like Macdonald's disillusioned UK SME patenters (Macdonald, 2003), or are they firms which have had one useful technological development but which are not in general "new to the world" innovators? Have they changed over time in their characteristics? Similarly Silverbrook stands out as a very unusual company - it operates in the area of high-speed printing where strategic patenting is well-known, and large quantities of patents are traded to ensure companies have the freedom to continue operations. Does Silverbrook constitute a model to which Australian firms should aspire? Or is it simply forced to take out this very large number of patents to have the freedom to operate within its particular technology field. But it is within the remaining 1,162 Australian firms patenting in the US that the more important answers for industry and innovation policy may lie. What kinds of firms are these? Are they small firms? Have they grown over time? Are they domestic firms or subsidiaries of overseas companies? Do they themselves have overseas operations? What are the technology fields within which they operate? A key issue is whether the hypothesis that Australian-based firms patenting in the USA are more innovative than equivalent firms who do not patent in the USA. Certainly they are likely to be more globally oriented. But innovative firms may, for a variety of reasons including availability of complementary assets, choose a more limited geographic area of operation, especially in their early years. This exploratory analysis addresses the question of whether data on overseas patenting can usefully address the limitations of domestic patenting data for purposes of industry and innovation policy analysis

    What are the costs and benefits of patent systems?

    No full text
    There do not appear to be any cost-benefit assessments of the impact of patent systems, nor any data that can be used to directly assess the economic impact of patent systems. Discussions of patent policy therefore tend to be theoretical, and any evidence used is anecdotal rather than scientifically based. A wider search shows, however, that there is substantial empirical material on the costs and benefits of patent systems published in a very diverse range of journals and working papers. While these do not allow a full assessment of the economic impact of patent systems, they do provide useful evidence on many aspects of the impact of patent systems. This evidence is drawn together in this summary overview. The objective is to assist in a move towards an evidence-based discussion of patents as a central issue in innovation policy
    corecore