14,104 research outputs found

    Commonality in the LME aluminium and copper volatility processes through a Figarch lens

    Get PDF
    We consider dynamic representation of spot and three month aluminium and copper volatilities. These are the two most important metals traded in the London Metal Exchange (LME). They share common business cycle factors and are traded under identical contract specifications. We apply the bivariate FIGARCH model which allows parsimonious representation of long memory volatility processes. Our results show that spot and three month aluminium and copper volatilities follow long memory processes, that they exhibit a common degree of fractional integration and that the processes are symmetric. However, there is no evidence that the processes are fractionally cointegrated. This high degree of commonality may result from the common LME trading process

    Price Variability and Marketing Method in the Non-Ferrous Metals Industry

    Get PDF
    We examine the impact of the pricing regime on price variability with reference to the non-ferrous metals industry. Theoretical arguments are ambiguous, but in any case suggests that the extent of monopoly power is more important than the pricing regime as determinant of variability. Slade (1991) argued that metals price volatility increased in the nineteen eighties relative to the seventies, and that this was associated with a move from administered producer pricing to exchange pricing. This claims are only partially supported. Extension of Slade's sample to the present indicates that any early differences between the variability of producer and exchange prices have now vanished.Metals, Futures trading, Exchange pricing, Producer pricing, Price volatility

    Commonality in the LME aluminium and copper volatility processes through a Figarch lens

    Get PDF
    We consider dynamic representation of spot and three month aluminium and copper volatilities. These are the two most important metals traded in the London Metal Exchange (LME). They share common business cycle factors and are traded under identical contract specifications. We apply the bivariate FIGARCH model which allows parsimonious representation of long memory volatility processes. Our results show that spot and three month aluminium and copper volatilities follow long memory processes, that they exhibit a common degree of fractional integration and that the processes are symmetric. However, there is no evidence that the processes are fractionally cointegrated. This high degree of commonality may result from the common LME trading process.

    Exchange rate dynamics in crawling-band systems

    Get PDF
    In this note we show that an exchange rate crawling-band system can borrow a portion of those aspects of a target zone that lead to its stabilizing effects on the exchange rate, depending on the relationship between the crawl rate and the drift of the fundamentals process. If the crawl rate is sufficiently high (with respect to the drift), the crawling-band is similar to a free float regime. As the crawl rate decreases, the crawling-band system collapses to a standard target zone.crawling band

    Quantum error correction may delay, but also cause, entanglement sudden death

    Full text link
    Dissipation may cause two initially entangled qubits to evolve into a separable state in a finite time. This behavior is called entanglement sudden death (ESD). We study to what extent quantum error correction can combat ESD. We find that in some cases quantum error correction can delay entanglement sudden death but in other cases quantum error correction may cause ESD for states that otherwise do not suffer from it. Our analysis also shows that fidelity may not be the best measure to compare the efficiency of different error correction codes since the fidelity is not directly coupled to a state's remaining entanglement.Comment: 3 figure

    Would Global Patent Protection be too Weak without International Coordination?

    Get PDF
    This paper analyzes the setting of national patent policies in the global economy. In the standard model with free trade and social-welfare-maximizing governments Ă  la Grossman and Lai (2004), cross-border positive policy externalities induce individual countries to select patent strengths that are weaker than is optimal from a global perspective. The paper introduces three new features to the analysis: trade barriers, firm heterogeneity in terms of productivity and political economy considerations in setting patent policies. The first two features (trade barriers interacting with firm heterogeneity) tend to reduce the size of cross-border externalities in patent protection and therefore make national IPR policies closer to the global optimum. With firm lobbying creating profit-bias of the government, it is even possible that the equilibrium strength of global patent protection is greater than the globally efficient level. Thus, the question of under-protection or not is an empirical one. Based on calibration exercises, we find that there would be global under-protection of patent rights when there is no international policy coordination. Furthermore, requiring all countries to harmonize their patent standards with the equilibrium standard of the most innovative country (the US) does not lead to global over-protection of patent rights.intellectual property rights, patents, TRIPS, harmonization

    Cross-coupled doa trackers

    Get PDF
    A new robust, low complexity algorithm for multiuser tracking is proposed, modifying the two-stage parallel architecture of the estimate-maximize (EM) algorithm. The algorithm copes with spatially colored noise, large differences in source powers, multipath, and crossing trajectories. Following a discussion on stability, the simulations demonstrate an asymptotic and tracking behavior that neither the EM nor a nonparallelized tracker can emulate.Peer ReviewedPostprint (published version
    • …
    corecore