38 research outputs found

    La régulation du "nouveau capitalisme". Analyses positives et recommandations normatives comparées

    Get PDF
    Les approches en termes de régulation ont analysé l'avènement du «nouveau capitalisme» à partir de trois types d'hypothèse : la crise du fordisme, le capitalisme cognitif et la violence de la monnaie. Cette dernière hypothèse est ici privilégiée. Les recommandations normatives par certains de ses partisans s'ordonnent parfois autour de l'allocation universelle, la réforme du droit du travail ou encore l'actionnariat salarié. En vertu du principe selon lequel «on ne saurait déduire ce qui doit être de ce qui est», ces recommansations ne découlent aucunement de l'analyse positive proposée.crise du fordisme; capitalisme actionnarial; régulation

    Décentralisation des relations professionnelles et gestion de l'emploi en France

    Get PDF
    Les lois Auroux de 1982 ont impulsé, en France, un mouvement de décentralisation des relations professionnelles. On peut effectivement constater, au cours de la dernière décennie, un développement notable des accords d'entreprise. Aux yeux de l'observateur, ce mouvement ne doit pas occulter, malgré tout, ni la pérennité des accords de branche, ni l'importante variable des accords d'entreprise selon les secteurs et les tailles d'entreprise ni, enfin, le fait que la dynamique n'est pas nécessairement la même d'un thème de négociation à l'autre. Une enquête menée dans deux secteurs (électronique et santé) permet de spécifier les limites de la décentralisation en matière de négociation sur l'emploi.The 1982 Auroux laws in France served to bring unions and enterprises closer together. Whereas historically labour relations had been based on confrontation between a labour movement in which the "revolutionary" spirit had prevalled for a long time, and on a management which had carefully avoided the introduction of collective bargaining in firms, the 1980s were characterized by a significant move towards decentralization of negotiations to enterprises and establishments. In the first part of this article, it is shown that, in fact, the Auroux laws contributed to this change: in 1981, barely 1500 enterprise — level agreements were registered in France; in 1992 there were 6370 such agreements. Nevertheless, it is worth pointing out three complementary phenomena. First, the law related to employees' freedom of expression has had limited success: according to a recent report, in reality groups for self— expression seldom function and do so poorly. Weak union involvement and management participation policies (quality circles) have undeniably contributed to weakening the interest in and importance of these groups. Secondly, the growth of enterprise — level collective bargaining has not resulted in a decline in industry — wide agreements (their number has remained stable throughout the decade); nor is their growth homogeneous (such agreements are increasingly the reality in large industrial sector firms). Finally, the dynamic varies according to the objects of negotiation. Hence, the following observations: a certain importance given to salaries in negotiations at both the industry and enterprise levels, industry — level negotiation giving way to enterprise — level negotiation regarding work time; a renewal of energy though the volume of agreements remains limited; and interprofessional industry — and enterprise — level negotiations on the issue of employment.The aim of the second part of the article is, precisely, to evaluate the impact of negotiations on the management of employment relations in two sectors that are at first glance opposites: this interest is based on a study conducted by the two authors in which they examine the management of redundant personnel in a sector in crisis (electronics) and the management of labour shortages in a protected public sector (health care).Firstly, during recent years programs have multiplied in the electronics sector to deal with layoffs. In order to institute preventive action, in 1990 and 1991, the social actors established joint committees on employment whose mission was to make forecasts of employment in the industry in order to formulate ways to deal with the effects of fluctuating employment (forecasts of movement of the workforce, establishment of special training programs, and so on). In reality, for reasons related as much to the desire of employers to bring back the management of employment relations to the level of the enterprise as to the difficulty in adjusting trade union structures to the reality of a specific industry (electronics and not the metallurgical industry, which remains the usual framework for negotiations), these committees have scarcely been effective. Furthermore, it was observed that there is a real asymmetry between the enterprise (strategic level where important decisions about employment are made) and the establishments. Within the latter, in spite of rights given to union organizations, they, as well as the local administrations which are sometimes just as powerless as themselves, can only negotiate the consequences of strategies elaborated at the group and enterprise levels. Thus one of the major limitations of the policy of decentralization of industrial relations can be clearly seen here. As regards the health care sector, its System of industrial relations is structured around a statutory logic regulating recruitment, remuneration and employment of permanent personnel. Since the hospital reforms of July 31, 1991, with a concern for democratization similar to the one which was behind the Auroux laws, dialogue between all actors can take place within a series of councils who are responsible for both investment programs and internal regulations, etc. The fact remains that in the case of electronics, decisions about the volume of employment are made at the central level (the Ministry): the volume of employment is thus a fact that the actors cannot negotiate because it is the result of political arbitration and certain financial constraints. This weak union influence on determining factors of employment policy was one of the reasons, among many others, for the emergence of new forms of collective action during the second half of the 1980s. During the conflicts that characterized this period, nurses and auxiliary nurses went beyond union and institutional channels of communication in aid of sectorial organizations. This was significant each time, the conflicts having a direct impact on topics that normally cannot be debated within the framework of joint committees: such is the case of the level of employment, re-establishment of indexation and recruitment terms. This is amply demonstrated in the two sectorial studies that were conducted. These two case studies tend to show that in France the movement towards decentralization not only increases the tendency to negotiate salary changes, management of work time, and so on in a compartmentalized way, but also makes it more difficult for union organizations to negotiate employment policy determinants at the enterprise level. Furthermore, beyond differences between the private and public sectors that many researchers have rightly emphasized, it appears to us that the two sectors examined continue to have certain common characteristics which reflect quite well the difficulty experienced by the current French trade union movement in adapting itself structurally to the new social and economic context

    Long short-term memory (LSTM) neural networks for short-term water level prediction in Mekong river estuaries

    Get PDF
    This study firstly adopts a state-of-the-art deep learning approach based on a Long Short-Term Memory (LSTM) neural network for predicting the hourly water level of Mekong estuaries in Vietnam. The LSTM models were developed from around 8,760 hourly data points within 2018 and were evaluated using the Nash-Sutcliffe efficiency coefficient (NSE), mean absolute error (MAE), and root mean square error (RMSE). The results showed that the NSE values for the training and testing steps were both above 0.98, which can be regarded as very good performance. Furthermore, the RMSE were between 0.09 and 0.11 m for the training and between 0.10 and 0.12 m for the testing, while MAE for the training ranged from 0.07 to 0.08 m and varied from 0.08 to 0.10 m for the testing. The LSTM networks appear to enable high precision and robustness in water level time series prediction. The outcomes of this research have crucial implications in river water level predictions, especially from the viewpoint of employing deep learning algorithms

    Whither Heterodoxy? Or Where Is Heterodox Economics Going?

    No full text

    10+1 questions sur la dette: questions posées par Pierre-Luc Séguillon

    No full text
    Pourquoi la dette publique a-t-elle explosé depuis 30 ans ? Sommes-nous les plus mauvais élèves de la classe mondiale ? A qui profite la dette publique ? L'Etat est-il top ou mauvais dépensier ? Existe-t-il de bons ou de mauvais déficits ? Les économistes sont-ils tous d'accord au sujet de la dette ? Faut-il augmenter, stabiliser ou réduire les dépenses obligatoires ? Faut-il réformer le financement de l'assurance-maladie et des retraites ? Faut-il durcir le pacte de stabilité ? Comment amener la France à tirer parti de l'économie de la connaissance pour améliorer sa compétitivité, produire et exporter davantage

    Sarkonomics

    No full text

    Sarkonomics

    No full text
    Gsell Stéphane. Chronique archéologique africaine. In: Mélanges d'archéologie et d'histoire, tome 22, 1902. pp. 301-345

    Vive l'impôt !

    No full text
    Pour réduire les inégalités, la République avait conçu un impôt universel et progressif. Il était un attribut essentiel de la citoyenneté, l'ami de la croissance, le garant de notre modèle social et du service public. Qu'en reste-t-il ? La fiscalité et ses injustices sont aujourd'hui dans l'ombre du débat politique. A l'heure où l'Etat social risque d'être sacrifié au profit d'une nouvelle société de rentiers, il devient urgent de réinventer l'impôt

    Le fabuleux destin de la courbe de Phillips : Les théories de l'inflation et du chômage après Keynes

    No full text
    Cet ouvrage souligne l'actualité du projet keynésien à l'heure où la macroéconomie dominante arestauré le point de vue classique sur le chômage et la monnaie. Révisant la relation inflation chômage, les courbes de Phillips du deuxième et du troisième âge des monétaristes et des nouveaux keynésiens s'épuisent à recommander des "réformes structurelles"et politiques macroéconomiques restrictives, inaptes à combattre le chômage de masse. La postface de Marc Lavoie explore la pertinence d'une courbe de Phillips du quatrième âge d'inspiration postkeynésienne, inédite en France, indiquant que la demande crée l'offre et que sa stimulation est susceptible de n'être aucunement inflaitonniste dans le contexte de sous-emploi des hommes et des machines

    Refermons la parenthèse libérale !

    No full text
    Le virage libéral opéré en 1983 est-il réversible? Au carrefour de Marx et de Keynes, cet essai propose les fondements théoriques d'une nouvelle politique socialiste. Il montre que l'avènement du capitalisme actionnarial n'est pas le résultat d'un déterminisme inéluctable mais d'une confrontation sociale gagnée par la finance. Des nouvelles" stratégies pour l'emploi" aux "réformes" de la sécurité sociale en passant par "l'ouverture à la concurrence", il critique les solutions apportées par les divers gouvernements depuis 1983 et discute les propositions faussement radicales qui reviennent à appuyer la marche du nouveau capitalisme sur des béquilles éthiques. Il définit les objectifs économiques et sociaux esentiels d'une politique d'alternance appuyée sur un renouvellement de la démocratie en France et en Europe
    corecore