339 research outputs found
Face Value
There is growing evidence of systematic heterogeneity in behavior by observable characteristics, such as what one would see in a face. We ask, is there informational value in knowing these characteristics in a strategic interaction? Subjects are given the opportunity to purchase a photograph of their partner in the play of a trust game. Not everyone purchases the photo, even at prices as low as $0.20. Senders (first movers in the game) have a more inelastic demand for pictures than responders (second movers). White senders have a substantially higher demand than nonwhite senders or responders. For responders, there is no difference in demand for pictures across ethnicity or sex. White senders who pay to see the picture of their partner use the information to discriminate, sending significantly less to black responders than to white responders. Overall, responders return a higher percentage of the amount received as offers go up, but they do differentiate that percentage when they see the picture of the sender, returning more to a member of the same ethnicity. A face, it appears, has strategic value, especially for those who will use the information to differentiate their decisions.
Will the Working Poor Invest in Human Capital? A Laboratory Experiment
This paper presents the results of a laboratory experiment involving some 250 subjects in the Montreal area. The experiment focused on three main questions : (1) Will the working poor invest in various assets? (2) Are these subjects willing to delay consumption for substantial returns? (3) How do these subjects view risky choices? Answering these questions will help answering the key research question : Given the right incentive, will the working poor save to invest in human capital? To view the report, please click here : www.srdc.org/english/publications/workingpoor.pdf Ce rapport prĂ©sente les rĂ©sultats d'une expĂ©rience en laboratoire impliquant environ 250 sujets rĂ©sidant dans la rĂ©gion de MontrĂ©al. L'expĂ©rience tente de rĂ©pondre Ă trois questions : 1) Les travailleurs Ă faible revenu investissent-ils dans des actifs diversifiĂ©s?; 2) Les sujets sont-ils prĂȘts Ă reporter leur consommation dans le futur en Ă©change de rendements financiers substantiels?; 3) Comment ces sujets perçoivent-ils les choix risquĂ©s? Les rĂ©ponses Ă ces questions vont permettre d'Ă©clairer le sujet principal de cette recherche menĂ©e par le SRDC, Ă savoir : Si on leur procure les bonnes incitations, les travailleurs Ă faible revenu auront-ils tendance Ă Ă©pargner pour investir dans du capital humain? Pour visionner l'intĂ©gralitĂ© du rapport cliquez ici : http://www.srdc.org/uploads/workingpoor.pdf
Saving Decisions of the Working Poor: Short-and Long-Term Horizons
We explore the predictive capacity of short-horizon time preference decisions for long-horizon investment decisions. We use experimental evidence from a sample of Canadian working poor. Each subject made a set of decisions trading off present and future amounts of money. Decisions involved both short and long time horizons, with stakes ranging up to six hundred dollars. Short horizon preference decisions do well in predicting the long-horizon investment decisions. These short horizon questions are much less expensive to administer but yield much higher estimated discount rates. We find no evidence that the present-biased preference measures generated from the short-horizon time preference decisions indicate any bias in long-term investment decisions. We also show that individuals are heterogeneous with respect to discount rates generated by short-horizon time preference decisions and long-horizon time preference decisions. Dans cet article, nous Ă©valuons si les prĂ©fĂ©rences exprimĂ©es pour le prĂ©sent peuvent prĂ©dire les dĂ©cisions dâinvestissement dans le long terme. Lâarticle mobilise lâapproche de lâĂ©conomie expĂ©rimentale avec comme participants des travailleurs canadiens Ă faibles revenus. Chaque participant est invitĂ© Ă choisir entre une somme quâil peut toucher Ă trĂšs court terme et un montant plus Ă©levĂ©, mais qui ne lui sera versĂ© que plus tard dans le temps. Pour certains choix, les montants ne seront disponibles que dans 7 ans et peuvent atteindre jusquâĂ 600 $. Nous trouvons que les dĂ©cisions entre le prĂ©sent et un horizon de court terme permettent de prĂ©dire les arbitrages rĂ©alisĂ©s par les participants entre le prĂ©sent et des dĂ©cisions Ă plus long terme. Ce rĂ©sultat est important dans la mesure oĂč il est plus difficile et coĂ»teux dâĂ©tudier les dĂ©cisions de long terme que celles de court terme. Nous observons Ă©galement une forte hĂ©tĂ©rogĂ©nĂ©itĂ© entre les participants relativement Ă leurs taux dâescompte de court et de long terme.intertemporal choice, field experiments, risk attitudes, choix intertemporels, Ă©conomie expĂ©rimentale, attitudes vis-Ă -vis le risque
Human Capital Investment by the Poor: Informing Policy with Laboratory and Field Experiments
The purpose of the study is to collect information that can be used to design a policy to induce the poor to invest in human capital. We use laboratory experimental methodology to measure the preferences and choices of the target population of a proposed government policy. We recruited 256 subjects in Montreal, Canada; 72 percent had income below 120 percent of the Canadian poverty level. The combination of survey measures and actual decisions allows us to better understand individual heterogeneity in responses to different subsidy levels. Two behavioral characteristics, patience and attitude towards risk, are key to understanding the determinants of educational investment for the low-income individuals in this experiment. The decision to save for a family memberâs education is somewhat different from that of investing in oneâs own education. Again, patient participants were more likely to save for a family memberâs education, but in contrast to investing in oneâs own education, a subjectâs attitude towards risk played no role. Le but de cette Ă©tude est de recueillir des informations pour concevoir une politique publique afin dâinciter les pauvres Ă investir en capital humain. Nous utilisons lâapproche expĂ©rimentale pour mesurer les prĂ©fĂ©rences et les choix de la population ciblĂ©e. Nous avons recrutĂ© 256 sujets Ă MontrĂ©al. 72 % avaient un revenu infĂ©rieur Ă 120 % pour cent du seuil de faible revenu de Statistique Canada. La combinaison de mesures d'enquĂȘte et les dĂ©cisions rĂ©elles nous permettent de mieux comprendre l'hĂ©tĂ©rogĂ©nĂ©itĂ© individuelle dans les rĂ©ponses aux diffĂ©rents niveaux de subvention. Deux caractĂ©ristiques comportementales, la patience (dĂ©sir dâĂ©pargne) et l'attitude envers le risque, sont essentielles Ă la comprĂ©hension des dĂ©terminants de l'investissement Ă©ducatif pour les personnes Ă faible revenu dans cette expĂ©rience. La dĂ©cision dâinvestir dans l'Ă©ducation d'un membre de la famille est quelque peu diffĂ©rente de celle d'investir dans sa propre Ă©ducation. Encore une fois, les participants les plus patients sont les plus susceptibles d'Ă©pargner pour l'Ă©ducation d'un membre de la famille, mais au contraire, investir dans sa propre Ă©ducation, l'attitude d'un sujet vis-Ă -vis le risque ne joue aucun rĂŽle.Intertemporal choice, field experiments, risk attitudes, working poor, choix intertemporels, expĂ©riences sur le terrain, les attitudes vis-Ă -vis le risque, travailleurs pauvres
Loving the Longshot: Risk Taking with Skewed Gambles
To examine the effect of increased skewness on risk taking, we conduct controlled laboratory experiments. Our instrument is an adaption of the Eckel and Grossman (2002, 2008) risk measure (with six gamble choices). The Eckel and Grossman measure is a simplest, easy to understand, exercise that gives sufficient heterogeneity in choices while at the same time minimizing errors. Its simplicity also makes it easy to adapt. The adapted gamble choices are designed to have the same expected payoffs and risk as the original gamble choices, but to exhibit increasing degrees of right skewness. The adapted instrument is used to address the question; does skewness encourage greater or less risk taking? Does the possibility of winning a high-earnings, long shot encourage people into greater or less overall risk taking? It also permits us to confirm, in a controlled environment, that people prefer positive skewness
Face Value
There is growing evidence of systematic heterogeneity in behavior by observable characteristics, such as what one would see in a face. We ask, is there informational value in knowing these characteristics in a strategic interaction? Subjects are given the opportunity to purchase a photograph of their partner in the play of a trust game. Not everyone purchases the photo, even at prices as low as $0.20. Senders (first movers in the game) have a more inelastic demand for pictures than responders (second movers). White senders have a substantially higher demand than nonwhite senders or responders. For responders, there is no difference in demand for pictures across ethnicity or sex. White senders who pay to see the picture of their partner use the information to discriminate, sending significantly less to black responders than to white responders. Overall, responders return a higher percentage of the amount received as offers go up, but they do differentiate that percentage when they see the picture of the sender, returning more to a member of the same ethnicity. A face, it appears, has strategic value, especially for those who will use the information to differentiate their decisions
Giving to Government: Voluntary Taxation in the Lab
In the United States, there is widespread antipathy toward taxation, yet at the same time there are substantial voluntary donations to nonprofit organizations with missions that are parallel to those of many government agencies. In this paper we compare giving in the form of voluntary taxes paid to government agencies with giving in the form of voluntary donations to nonprofit organizations that have similar missions. In a laboratory experimental setting, subjects are given an endowment, and are given the opportunity to donate any part of the endowment to a government agency or to a nonprofit organization. We compare levels of giving to private and government organizations for four different causes (cancer research, disaster relief, education, and parks and wildlife) at three levels of government (federal, state and local). Within a session, subjects make 12 decisions: they complete all six separate decisions for each of two causes, selected randomly from the four listed above. We find that people are not averse to giving to government. On average, they give 22 percent of their budget to government when anonymity is ensured and giving is completely voluntary. However, they do show a preference for nonprofit charities by giving higher amounts for most causes and levels of government. The willingness to give is influenced by the cause and level of the organization, as well as perceptions of the organization
Care provision: An experimental investigation
In many principal-agent settings, the effort provided by the agent benefits a third party. In these settings, the quality of the work is determined, at least in part, by pro-social motivations. We present lab experiments that utilize a new three-player trust game to examine one such setting, care provision. Players include a principal, an agent, and a needy recipient. The principal can transfer resources to an agent, who then can transfer resources to the needy recipient; the latter transfers are tripled. As in the two-player version, we find high, but variable, levels of trust and reciprocity (agent transfers to target) in the baseline game. Two treatments allow us to gauge the impact of potential policy interventions to enhance care of the target recipient. The first provides a budget subsidy to the principle, and the second alters the effectiveness (multiplier) of the agentâs transfers. Results show that the behavior of the agent does not vary by treatment, and is determined primarily by the amount received from the principal. Principals, on the other hand, do respond to the policy changes. While budget subsidies increase the expenditure of the principal only slightly, policies impacting the agentâs efficiency increase the amount entrusted to them by principals and significantly impact the well-being of the recipient. Results suggest that policies that increase the effectiveness of care workers (the agents) may significantly impact the quality of work provided. Examples of such policies include increased worker training and reductions in red tape
Subsidizing Unit Donations: Matches, Rebates, and Discounts Compared
An influential result in the literature on charitable giving is that matching subsidies dominate rebate subsidies in raising funds. We investigate whether this result extends to âunit donationâ schemes, a popular alternative form of soliciting donations. There, the donorsâ choices are about the number of units of a charitable good to fund at a given unit price, rather than the amount of money to give. Comparing matches and rebates as well as simple discounts on the unit price, we find no evidence of dominance in our online experiment: The three subsidy types are equally effective overall. At a more disaggregate level, rebates lead to a higher likelihood of giving while matching and discount subsidies lead to larger donations by donors. This suggests that charities using a unit donation scheme enjoy additional degrees of freedom in choosing a subsidy type. Rebates merit additional consideration if the primary goal is to attract donors
Independent vs. Collaborative Fundraising: Understanding the Role of Information
We use âreal donationâ laboratory experiments to compare independent fundraising, where donation requests from different charities arrive sequentially to potential donors, with collaborative fundraising, where donation requests from different charities arrive simultaneously. We find that collaborative fundraising generates significantly larger total donations compared to independent fundraising. We show that the order of requests affects the level of donations only in independent fundraising; in particular, participants donated larger amounts to charities whose requests arrived earlier. We then test whether these differences might be explained by the informational asymmetry between these two fundraising mechanisms by varying the information received by the subjects
- âŠ