259 research outputs found
The Importance of Disagreeing: Contrarians and Extremism in the CODA model
In this paper, we study the effects of introducing contrarians in a model of
Opinion Dynamics where the agents have internal continuous opinions, but
exchange information only about a binary choice that is a function of their
continuous opinion, the CODA model. We observe that the hung election scenario
still exists here, but it is weaker and it shouldn't be expected in every
election. Finally, we also show that the introduction of contrarians make the
tendency towards extremism of the original model weaker, indicating that the
existence of agents that prefer to disagree might be an important aspect and
help society to diminish extremist opinions.Comment: 14 pages, 9 figure
Formation of Languages; Equality, Hierarchy and Teachers
A quantitative method is suggested, where meanings of words, and grammatic
rules about these, of a vocabulary are represented by real numbers. People meet
randomly, and average their vocabularies if they are equal; otherwise they
either copy from higher hierarchy or stay idle. Presence of teachers
broadcasting the same (but arbitrarily chosen) vocabulary leads the language
formations to converge more quickly.Comment: 10 pages, 3 (totally 8) figure
Truth seekers in opinion dynamics models
We modify the model of Deffuant et al. to distinguish true opinion among
others in the fashion of Hegselmann and Krause
. The basic features of both models
modified to account for truth seekers are qualitatively the same.Comment: RevTeX4, 2 pages, 1 figure in 6 eps file
About the Power to Enforce and Prevent Consensus by Manipulating Communication Rules
We explore the possibilities of enforcing and preventing consensus in
continuous opinion dynamics that result from modifications in the communication
rules. We refer to the model of Weisbuch and Deffuant, where agents adjust
their continuous opinions as a result of random pairwise encounters whenever
their opinions differ not more than a given bound of confidence \eps. A high
\eps leads to consensus, while a lower \eps leads to a fragmentation into
several opinion clusters. We drop the random encounter assumption and ask: How
small may \eps be such that consensus is still possible with a certain
communication plan for the entire group? Mathematical analysis shows that
\eps may be significantly smaller than in the random pairwise case. On the
other hand we ask: How large may \eps be such that preventing consensus is
still possible? In answering this question we prove Fortunato's simulation
result that consensus cannot be prevented for \eps>0.5 for large groups. %
Next we consider opinion dynamics under different individual strategies and
examine their power to increase the chances of consensus. One result is that
balancing agents increase chances of consensus, especially if the agents are
cautious in adapting their opinions. However, curious agents increase chances
of consensus only if those agents are not cautious in adapting their opinions.Comment: 21 pages, 6 figure
Monte Carlo Simulation of Deffuant opinion dynamics with quality differences
In this work the consequences of different opinion qualities in the Deffuant
model were examined. If these qualities are randomly distributed, no different
behavior was observed. In contrast to that, systematically assigned qualities
had strong effects to the final opinion distribution. There was a high
probability that the strongest opinion was one with a high quality.
Furthermore, under the same conditions, this major opinion was much stronger
than in the models without systematic differences. Finally, a society with
systematic quality differences needed more tolerance to form a complete
consensus than one without or with unsystematic ones.Comment: 8 pages including 5 space-consuming figures, fir Int. J. Mod. Phys. C
15/1
Continuous Opinions and Discrete Actions in Opinion Dynamics Problems
A model where agents show discrete behavior regarding their actions, but have
continuous opinions that are updated by interacting with other agents is
presented. This new updating rule is applied to both the voter and Sznajd
models for interaction between neighbors and its consequences are discussed.
The appearance of extremists is naturally observed and it seems to be a
characteristic of this model.Comment: 10 pages, 4 figures, minor changes for improved clarit
Multidimensional Consensus model on a Barabasi-Albert network
A Consensus Model according to Deffuant on a directed Barabasi-Albert network
was simulated. Agents have opinions on different subjects. A multi-component
subject vector was used. The opinions are discrete. The analysis regards
distribution and clusters of agents which are on agreement in the opinions of
the subjects. Remarkable results are on the one hand, that there mostly exists
no absolute consens. It determines depending on the ratio of number of agents
to the number of subjects, whether the communication ends in a consens or a
pluralism. Mostly a second robust cluster remains, in its size depending on the
number of subjects. Two agents agree either in (nearly) all or (nearly) no
subject. The operative parameter of the consens-formating-process is the
tolerance in change of views of the group-members.Comment: 14 pages including all 10 figures, for IJMPC 16, issue
Sélection de points en apprentissage actif. Discrépance et dispersion : des critères optimaux ?
National audienceNous souhaitons générer des bases d'apprentissage adaptées aux problèmes de classification. Nous montrons tout d'abord que les résultats théoriques privilégiant les suites à discrépance faible pour les problèmes de régression sont inadaptés aux problèmes de classification. Nous donnons ensuite des arguments théoriques et des résultats de simulations montrant que c'est la dispersion des points d'apprentissage qui est le critère pertinent à minimiser pour optimiser les performances de l'apprentissage en classification
- …