37 research outputs found

    Intrasac Pressure Waveforms After Endovascular Aneurysm Repair (EVAR) are a Reliable Marker of Type I Endoleaks, but not Type II or Combined Types: An Experimental Study

    Get PDF
    AbstractPurposeTo ascertain the nature of the pressure wave transmitted through aneurysm thrombus and the changes produced after endovascular repair and the development of type I and II endoleaks.MethodsA 25mm Talent endovascular graft was deployed in a latex model of an abdominal aortic aneurysm, which was incorporated in a pulsatile flow unit. The graft was surrounded by thrombus analogue to simulate conditions in vivo. Pressure waveforms in the sac were captured over 5s at 1000Hz in these settings: (i) no endoleaks (baseline), after introduction of (ii) type I (iii) type II and (iv) combined type I and II endoleaks. The arterial blood pressure settings used were 140/100 and 130/90mmHg, denoted the high and low settings, respectively. ANOVA in Minitab 13 was applied for statistical analysis.ResultsPulsatile waveforms were transmitted through the thrombus. Intrasac pressure after stent-grafting reduced to 110/107, 99/96mmHg (p<0.001) (high, low settings, respectively). Introduction of a type I endoleak caused this to rise to 120/112, 115/107mmHg (p<0.001, vs. baseline); after producing a type II endoleak these were 101/98, 91/88mmHg (p<0.001, vs. baseline). A combined type I and II endoleak produced intrasac pressures identical to that of a type I endoleak.ConclusionsIntrasac pressure waveforms following EVAR are easily defined following a type I endoleak. Waveforms obtained following type II endoleak simulation resemble the baseline waveform in an attenuated form. Intrasac pressures are, therefore, a reliable marker for type I, but not a type II endoleak. In the case of a combined endoleak, the type I endoleak waveform effectively masks that of the type II. Intrasac thrombus faithfully transmits intrasac pressures

    How Hartl exceeds Skiba: determinants of a successful career in academia

    Get PDF
    We present and analyze a life cycle model of a scientific career to investigate how the budget available for research related activities affects a scientist’s long run success in academia. Recognizing that reputation has a positive impact on obtaining research funds as well as on producing scientific output, we determine the optimal efforts of a scientist with respect to applying for research grants and costly science related activities to improve reputation, such as networking and inviting guest researchers, under the assumption that the total extent of these activities is limited by a time budget. We find that the optimal solution is history-dependent and study four different career paths which differ with respect to the initial reputation and the initial financial means to identify the determinants of success and failure in academia. It is shown that the extent to which a scientist finds the results of his or her work rewarding, has a substantial impact on whether the scientist will build up a successful career

    Leading bureaucracies to the tipping point: an alternative model of multiple stable equilibrium levels of corruption

    Get PDF
    We present a novel model of corruption dynamics in the form of a nonlinear optimal dynamic control problem. It has a tipping point, but one whose origins and character are distinct from that in the classic Schelling (1978) model. The decision maker choosing a level of corruption is the chief or some other kind of authority figure who presides over a bureaucracy whose state of corruption is influenced by the authority figure’s actions, and whose state in turn influences the pay-off for the authority figure. The policy interpretation is somewhat more optimistic than in other tipping models, and there are some surprising implications, notably that reforming the bureaucracy may be of limited value if the bureaucracy takes its cues from a corrupt leader

    A Dynamic Analysis of Schelling’s Binary Corruption Model: A Competitive Equilibrium Approach

    No full text
    Schelling (in Micromotives and Macrobehavior, Norton, New York, 1978) suggested a simple binary choice model to explain the variation of corruption levels across societies. His basic idea was that the expected profitability of engaging in corruption depends on its prevalence. The key result of the so-called Schelling diagram is the existence of multiple equilibria and a tipping point. The present paper puts Schelling’s essentially static approach into an intertemporal setting. We show how the existence of an unstable interior steady state leads to thresholds such that history alone or history in addition to expectations (or coordination) is necessary to determine the long-run outcome. In contrast to the related literature, which classifies these two cases according to whether the unstable equilibrium is a node or a focus, the actual differentiation is more subtle because even a node can lead to an overlap of solution paths such that the initial conditions alone are insufficient to uniquely determine the competitive equilibrium. Another insight is that a (transiently) cycling competitive equilibrium can dominate the direct and monotonic route to a steady state, even if the direct route is feasible
    corecore