68 research outputs found

    The Economic Legacy of Divorced and Separated Women in Old Age

    Get PDF
    Although progress has been made over the last 20 years, the burden of a low income in old age is still carried by unattached women. Few researchers, however, have examined exactly where the burden of poverty falls within the category of unattached older women or the nature of this poverty. Like any other group of older Canadians, unattached women are not a homogenous population. The category of 'unattached' includes the separated, divorced, widowed and ever single, all of whom face different circumstances in old age because of differences over the life course. Using SLID data we examine income and sources of income from 1993 to 1999 to identify differences among these groups. The findings indicate that the separated and divorced are the poorest of all older unattached women in Canada. A key source of the difference is the growth in private pension incomes.low income; old age; unattached women; SLID

    The Economic Legacy of Divorced and Separated Women in Old Age

    Get PDF
    Although progress has been made over the last 20 years, the burden of a low income in old age is still carried by unattached women. Few researchers, however, have examined exactly where the burden of poverty falls within the category of unattached older women or the nature of this poverty. Like any other group of older Canadians, unattached women are not a homogenous population. The category of "unattached" includes the separated, divorced, widowed and ever single, all of whom face different circumstances in old age because of differences over the life course. Using SLID data we examine income and sources of income from 1993 to 1999 to identify differences among these groups. The findings indicate that the separated and divorced are the poorest of all older unattached women in Canada. A key source of the difference is the growth in private pension incomes.low income; old age; unattached women; SLID

    Shifting Skill Demand and the Canada-US Unemployment Gap: Evidence from Prime-Age Men

    Get PDF
    This paper considers the possible role of shifts in labour demand away from unskilled workers, combined with an institutionally- generated greater labour supply elasticity in Canada, in explaining the apparent secular increase in Canadian male unemployment, and in explaining the emergence of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap in the 1980's. Using comparable data on annual weeks worked and unemployed in both countries, we identify four main facts which are consistent with such this explanation: Both Canada and the US experienced wage polarization over this period, with substantial real wage declines for unskilled men; annual weeks worked fell disproportionately among unskilled workers in both countries; responses of weeks worked to wage declines were more elastic in Canada; and aggregate movements out of employment over this period corresponded closely to movements into unemployment in Canada. Interestingly, however, unskilled U.S. men were more likely than Canadians to leave the labour force as their employment fell, adding further to the Canada-U.S. unemployment gap. As well, some fairly substantial decreases in weeks worked are observed quite high up in the Canadian wage distribution, where wages did not fall appreciably. The latter changes cannot easily be explained by a shifts in labour demand alone.

    Willingness-to-Pay for Improved Air Quality in Hamilton-Wentworth: A Choice Experiment

    Get PDF
    Prepared for Hamilton-Wentworth Air Quality Initiative pursuant to a memorandum of understanding among McMaster University, the Ontario Ministry of Environment and Energy and the Regional Municipality of Hamilton-Wentworth, dated November 5, 1996.

    Persistence and Academic Success in University

    Get PDF
    We use a unique set of linked administrative data sets to explore the determinants of persistence and academic success in university. The explanatory power of high school grades greatly dominates that of other variables such as university program, gender, and neighbourhood and high school characteristics. Indeed, high school and neighbourhood characteristics, such as average standardized test scores for a high school or average neighbourhood income, have weak links with success in university.university success, high school, neighbourhood.

    The Impact of Cost on the Choice of University: Evidence from Ontario

    Get PDF
    This paper provides the first Canadian study of the link between cost to the student and the choice of university. Over the past two decades, there has been a substantial increase in the differences among Ontario universities in “net cost” defined as tuition and fees minus the expected value to an academically strong student of a guaranteed merit scholarship. Our estimates generally indicate no relationship between net cost and the overall share of strong applicants that a university is able to attract. An increase in net cost is associated with an increase in the ratio of strong students from high income neighborhoods to strong students from middle income and low income neighborhoods in Arts and Science programs but not in Commerce and Engineering. Finally, more advantaged students are more likely to attend university, but merit aid is not of disproportionate benefit to those from more economically advantaged backgrounds given registration.health education and welfare, university, choice, cost.

    Wage Inflation and the Distribution of Unemployement

    Get PDF
    Les rĂ©sultats dĂ©cevants que les recherchistes ont obtenus en essayant de dĂ©couvrir des courbes de Phillips stables obligent Ă  en examiner de nouveau les fondements thĂ©oriques. MĂȘme si l'on a fait en ces derniĂšres annĂ©es beaucoup d'effort pour tenir compte de l'hypothĂšse de prĂ©visions inflationnistes, on a aussi considĂ©rĂ© attentivement les relations entre les taux d'inflation et les taux de chĂŽmage nationaux et rĂ©gionaux. Quelles que soient les directions dans lesquelles les recherches se sont orientĂ©es, on est arrivĂ© Ă  la conclusion qu'il n'existe pas de marchĂ© du travail « global », mais qu'il y a, Ă  l'intĂ©rieur d'une Ă©conomie nationale, plusieurs marchĂ©s du travail interreliĂ©s. Dans leur article, les auteurs ont analysĂ© le problĂšme des courbes de Phillips rĂ©gionales « globales » et quelques-uns des problĂšmes qu'elles soulĂšvent. À partir d'Ă©tudes thĂ©oriques rĂ©centes faites sur le sujet en Grande-Bretagne et en AmĂ©rique du Nord, ils ont essayĂ© de montrer que plus la dispersion du chĂŽmage Ă  travers diffĂ©rents secteurs de l'Ă©conomie est marquĂ©e plus la courbe de Phillips a tendance Ă  glisser vers la droite, que la direction de l'effet de dispersion est ambiguĂ« lorsqu'il y a mobilitĂ© de la main-d'oeuvre d'une rĂ©gion Ă  l'autre et, enfin, que, mĂȘme quand il n'y a pas migration de la main-d'oeuvre, il ne s'ensuit pas nĂ©cessairement un effet de dispersion.L'Ă©tude de Lipsey a considĂ©rĂ© l'hypothĂšse de l'existence d'une Ă©conomie divisĂ©e en deux marchĂ©s du travail en supposant un taux de chĂŽmage diffĂ©rent de l'un Ă  l'autre alors que le taux de chĂŽmage global demeure constant. Il en rĂ©sulte que les salaires augmentent plus rapidement dans la rĂ©gion oĂč le taux de chĂŽmage est bas qu'ils ne baissent dans celle oĂč le taux de chĂŽmage est le plus Ă©levĂ©. Lipsey en conclut donc que plus la diffĂ©rence entre les taux de chĂŽmage est grande entre les deux secteurs, plus l'indice des taux de salaire a tendance Ă  s'accroĂźtre. Dans le cas du Canada, il devient Ă©vident qu'il faut repenser la thĂ©orie de Lipsey. Un autre auteur, Archibald, a montrĂ© qu'il n'y a pas lieu de s'en prĂ©occuper en autant que le taux de changement de l'indice global des salaires est construit de telle sorte que les taux individuels de salaire soient pondĂ©rĂ©s en tenant compte de la main-d'oeuvre existant dans chacune des deux rĂ©gions. Le but de l'article est de dĂ©montrer que le raisonnement apportĂ© par Archibald Ă  l'appui de la thĂ©orie de Lipsey ne vaut plus s'il y a migration de la main-d'oeuvre d'une rĂ©gion Ă  l'autre. Or, comme la migration des sans-travail des rĂ©gions Ă  haut taux de chĂŽmage aux rĂ©gions Ă  taux de chĂŽmage bas est un phĂ©nomĂšne bien Ă©tabli au Canada et aux États-Unis, les auteurs expriment l'opinion que l'analyse d'Archibald n'a pas tellement de signification, car, comme le laissent voir les Ă©tudes de Brechling pour les États-Unis et celles de Kaliski et de Thirsk pour le Canada, il n'existe pas d'effet de dispersion.Cependant, lorsqu'il y a dispersion des taux de chĂŽmage, les recherchistes peuvent Ă©galement vouloir mesurer le degrĂ© de dispersion dans la courbe de Phillips « globale ». Pour ce faire, il faut que les changements globaux dans les donnĂ©es relatives aux salaires soient construites de façon que la pondĂ©ration de l'ensemble tienne compte des proportions de main-d'oeuvre. En rĂ©sumĂ©, si l'on considĂšre que les sans-travail Ă©migrent d'une rĂ©gion du Canada Ă  l'autre, il n'est aucunement surprenant que les Ă©tudes empiriques existantes soient impuissantes Ă  dĂ©tecter un effet de dispersion positif. La consĂ©quence de cette ambiguĂŻtĂ© signifie qu'on ne peut dĂ©couvrir une courbe de Phillips d'ensemble stable d'oĂč il rĂ©sulte que les tentatives en vue d'incorporer la variable d'un changement des taux auquel on s'attend s'avĂšrent un test nullement appropriĂ©de l'hypothĂšse de l'accĂ©lĂ©ration.The authors re-examine the question of aggregating regional Phillips curves and suggest some problems with the empirical work to date

    The Transition from Good to Poor Health: An Econometric Study of the Older Population

    Get PDF
    This is a study of the influence of socioeconomic factors on the state of health of older Canadians. Three years of panel data from the Survey of Labour and Income Dynamics are used to model the transition probabilities between good and poor health. Care is taken to avoid the problem of endogeneity of income in modelling its effects, and to adjust reported income to free it from its strong association with age at the time of the survey. Of particular note are the significant effects found for income, in spite of universal public health care coverage. Significant effects are found also for age, education, and other variables.Socioeconomic factors and health; older population; panel data

    Healthy Aging at Older Ages: Are Income and Education Important?

    Get PDF
    Being higher on the socioeconomic scale is correlated with being in better health, but is there is a causal relationship? Using three years of longitudinal data for individuals aged 50 and older from the Canadian Survey of Labour and Income Dynamics, we study the health transitions for those who were in good health in the first year, focussing especially on income and education. The initial good health restriction removes from the sample those whose incomes may have been affected by a previous history of poor health, thus avoiding a well known problem of econometric endogeneity. We then ask, for those in good health, whether later transitions in health status are related to socioeconomic status. We find that they are that changes in health status over the subsequent two years are related in particular to income and education.aging, health, income, education
    • 

    corecore