Archive of European Integration
Annual status report from the Commission on the Guarantee Fund and its management in 1999. COM (2000) 246 final, 27 April 2000
Community social policy: Commission proposes the extention of qualified majority voting. Trade Union Information Bulletin No. 3/91
Commission Decision of 16 November 1981 on the granting of financial support for demonstration projects in the field of geothermal energy. C(81) 1705 final, 16 November 1981
Present Santer calls for Confidence Pact on Employment. Trade Union Information Bulletin No. 1/96
The post-Lisbon role of the European Parliament in the EU's Common Commercial Policy: Implications for bilateral trade negotiations. EU Diplomacy Paper 05/2012, July 2012
This paper sets out to conduct an empirical analysis of the post-Lisbon role of the European Parliament (EP) in the EU’s Common Commercial Policy through an examination of the ‘deep and comprehensive’ bilateral Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs) currently negotiated as part of the EU’s Global Europe strategy. The EU-Korea and EU-India FTAs are used as case studies in order to determine the implications of
the EP’s enhanced trade powers on the processes, actors and outcomes of EU bilateral trade policy. The EP is now endowed with the ‘hard power’ of consent in the
ratification phase of FTAs, acting as a threat to strengthen its ‘soft power’ to influence negotiations. The EP is developing strategies to influence the mandate and now plays an important role in the implementation of FTAs. The entry of this new player on the Brussels trade policy field has brought about a shift in the institutional balance of power and opened up the EP as a new point of access for trade policy lobbyists. Finally, increased EP involvement in EU trade policy has brought about a
politicisation of EU trade policy and greater normative outcomes of FTAs
The Malleable Politics of Activation Reform: the ‘Hartz’ Reforms in Comparative Perspective
In this paper we compare the Hartz reforms in Germany with three other major labor market activation reforms carried out by center-left governments. Two of the cases, Britain and Germany, involved radically neoliberal “mandatory” activation policies, whereas in the Netherlands and Ireland radical activation change took a very different “enabling” form. Two of the cases, Ireland and Germany, were
path deviant, Britain and the Netherlands were path dependent. We explain why Germany underwent
“mandatory” and path deviant activation by focusing on two features of the policy discourse. First, the
coordinative (or elite level) discourse was “ensilaged” sealing policy formation off from dissenting actors
and, until belatedly unwrapped for enactment, from the wider communicative (legitimating) discourse.
This is what the British and German cases had in common and the result was reform that viewed long term
unemployment as personal failure rather than market failure. Second, although the German policy-making
system lacked the “authoritative” features that facilitated reform in the British case, and the Irish policymaking
system lacked the “reflexive” mechanisms that facilitated reform in the Dutch case, in both
Germany and Ireland the communicative discourses were reshaped by novel institutional vehicles (the
Hartz Commission in the German case, FÁS in the Irish case) that served to fundamentally alter systemconstitutive
perceptions about policy. In the Irish and German cases “government by commission”
created a realignment of advocacy coalitions with one coalition acquiring a new, ideologically-dominant
and path deviating narrative. The findings suggest that major reform of labor market and welfare state
policy may be much more malleable than previously thought