Mean-variance hedging for continuous processes: New proofs and examples

Abstract

Let XX be a special semimartingale of the form X=X0+M+dMλ^X=X_0+M+\int d\langle M\rangle\,\widehat\lambda and denote by K^=λ^trdMλ^\widehat K=\int \widehat\lambda^{\rm tr}\,d\langle M\rangle\,\widehat\lambda the mean-variance tradeoff process of XX. Let Θ\Theta be the space of predictable processes θ\theta for which the stochastic integral G(θ)=θdXG(\theta)=\int\theta\,dX is a square-integrable semimartingale. For a given constant cRc\in{\Bbb R} and a given square-integrable random variable HH, the mean-variance optimal hedging strategy ξ(c)\xi^{(c)} by definition minimizes the distance in L2(P){\cal L}^2(P) between HcH-c and the space GT(Θ)G_T(\Theta). In financial terms, ξ(c)\xi^{(c)} provides an approximation of the contingent claim HH by means of a self-financing trading strategy with minimal global risk. Assuming that K^\widehat K is bounded and continuous, we first give a simple new proof of the closedness of GT(Θ)G_T(\Theta) in L2(P){\cal L}^2(P) and of the existence of the FÃllmer-Schweizer decomposition. If moreover XX is continuous and satisfies an additional condition, we can describe the mean-variance optimal strategy in feedback form, and we provide several examples where it can be computed explicitly. The additional condition states that the minimal and the variance-optimal martingale measures for XX should coincide. We provide examples where this assumption is satisfied, but we also show that it will typically fail if K^T\widehat K_T is not deterministic and includes exogenous randomness which is not induced by XX.Mean-variance hedging, stochastic integrals, minimal martingale measure, FÃllmer-Schweizer decomposition, variance-optimal martingale measure

    Similar works

    Full text

    thumbnail-image

    Available Versions

    Last time updated on 14/01/2014