123 research outputs found

    Pay for Play: The Compensated Leisure Flaw of Contract Damages

    Get PDF
    Contract damages aim to leave the injured party in as good a position as if the contract had been fulfilled. But discharged laborers often obtain a much better result due to the lack of a reduction for their excused work effort on breach. After first exposing the problematic ramifications of this unjustified deviation, this Article then provides two workable corrections

    Goodwill Hunting Gone Bad: Tax Law ’s Outmoded Treatment of Goodwill

    Get PDF
    Goodwill reflects the positive consumer association with a business. Goodwill thus overlaps with trademarks and other related assets. This close association impedes the separation of goodwill value from such related assets. Difficulties thus arise when the tax law treats goodwill more (or less) favorably than related intangible assets.For instance, the tax law previously denied any depreciation deductions for goodwill. Business buyers thus often allocated their costs away from goodwill and towards related assets like depreciable customer lists. The IRS responded with the initial “goodwill hunting” wave, challenging taxpayers’ low goodwill valuations. Congress addressed this litigious area in 1993 with new, matching depreciation rules for purchased goodwill and related intangible assets.But the goodwill hunting problem remains, albeit with reversed roles, due to other provisions which treat goodwill more favorably than other intangibles. Taxpayers now overstate goodwill with the government in defense against this second goodwill hunting wave. For instance, U.S. corporations inflate goodwill on transfers to foreign subsidiaries given a special gain avoidance rule on such transfers for goodwill. While recent regulations have lessened these particular attempts, the Treasury Department’s limited authority prevented a full response for these subsidiary transfers. In addition, similar inconsistent tax rules incentivize high goodwill claims by taxpayers to obtain either more favorable capital gains rates or better foreign tax credit usage.This Article proposes four precise fixes to counteract these negative goodwill manipulations. These changes efficiently draw upon existing tax provisions. Such utilization of tried and tested provisions counteracts the status quo bias against untested reform proposals. These four changes together forge a common theme: the pressing need for a more uniform tax treatment of goodwill and other closely-related intangibles. With these changes, Congress would restore the positive association of goodwill back to the tax law

    A Progressive Consumption Tax for Individuals: An Alternative Hybrid Approach

    Get PDF
    Dissatisfaction with the existing income tax has increased in recent years. Practical problems with the income tax base create numerous loopholes, increasingly exploited by well-advised taxpayers. For the most part, these gaps are attributable to the income tax\u27s realization requirement, under which taxpayers report gains and losses as realized through market transactions. A consumption tax appeals as a response to these significant current loopholes since realization loses its significance under a consumption-based tax. The consumption tax\u27s appeal has been further enhanced by the recent and growing recognition of the narrow difference between income and consumption taxes, assuming away practical problems. Contrary to the long-standing belief that the income tax imposes an excess tax burden on all investment return, recent scholarship establishes that, relative to a pure income tax, the consumption tax relinquishes the tax burden on only the risk-free investment return. Accordingly, the consumption tax addresses the loopholes while relinquishing relatively little. Despite such threshold appeal, a consumption tax has not yet replaced the income tax. This Article descriptively explains this failure through an analysis of the leading progressive consumption tax proposal: the cash flow tax. The Article recaps the serious offsetting concerns raised by commentary on the cash flow tax, exhibiting how such concerns relate primarily to the cash flow tax\u27s wholesale removal of current tax on saved wages. Specifically, the lack of any current tax on saved wages raises tax avoidance, transition, and revenue concerns. In addition, saving decisions could be impacted in undesirable ways under a cash flow tax with progressive rates. Accordingly, the case for the consumption tax has been weakened by these concerns. The normative portion of this Article then presents a new progressive consumption tax proposal: a hybrid approach. Like the current income tax, the hybrid approach generally would tax wages, even if saved for future consumption. In addition, the hybrid approach would utilize a modified cash flow approach to tax the excess of (i) savings withdrawals for consumption, over (ii) previously saved wages, increased by the risk-free return thereon. As a result, the hybrid approach would capture the benefits of consumption taxation without the disabling problems of the cash flow tax. As discussed in the Article, the hybrid approach achieves this result since (i) the wage tax component addresses the cash flow tax concerns, and (ii) the modified cash flow component addresses the income tax problems

    The Untaxed King of South Beach: LeBron James and the NBA Salary Cap

    Get PDF
    In contrast to Major League Baseball, the National Basketball Association (NBA) has a salary cap designed to provide every team an equal and fair chance of competing for the championship. The Miami Heat\u27s recent, incredible success in signing the game\u27s three most hotly desired free agents, including mega-superstars LeBron James and Dwyane Wade, therefore flies in the face of the NBA\u27s attempted level playing field. How could one team so outmaneuver all the others in a sport that tried to eliminate such uncompetitive results via a salary cap? As discussed in this Article, the answer lies in the law of unintended consequences and perverse incentives. Some NBA teams are located in more attractive jurisdictions with nicer amenities or lower costs, such as taxes. For instance, Miami provides a highly favorable climate both as to weather and taxes because Florida does not have a state income tax. In the absence of any salary cap limitations, teams in higher tax jurisdictions could compete better with Miami for free-agent players by offering higher salaries to offset the extra tax. But the NBA salary cap, by its very terms, blocks this usual free market response. Having flagged this perverse and unintended benefit to the no-tax clubs like Miami, this Article then proposes an appropriate solution. Rather than scrapping the salary cap and restoring a competitive advantage to the wealthier clubs, a relatively simple state tax adjustment to the cap amounts would counteract the rich clubs\u27 advantage without substituting an unintended benefit to the no-tax clubs. To achieve this result, the salary cap amounts of no-tax teams simply should be reduced by a percentage equal to the highest state tax rate of any NBA team. After making this simple adjustment, this Article then refutes more sophisticated arguments as to why the proposed adjustment might go too far

    Progressive Consumption Taxes

    Get PDF
    Recent intellectual and political forces have moved the consumption tax to the forefront of tax policy debate. Since traditional flat-rate consumption taxes like the VAT raise serious distributional concerns, tax scholars have responded with innovative progressive consumption taxes. Two such taxes - the Hybrid Approach and the X-tax - were independently analyzed in a recent symposium on fundamental tax reform. These two proposals contain striking similarities. Both would tax individuals at progressive rates on their wages, with a separate tax on consumption less wages. Important differences exist, though, regarding the latter tax. The Hybrid Approach would impose such tax on individuals while the X-tax contemplates a VAT-like tax on all businesses. The X-tax and the Hybrid Approach are intriguing as they address the distributional objections to conventional consumption taxes. Standing alone, however, each raises problematic implementation tradeoffs. On the one hand, the X-tax simplifies individual tax reporting compared to the Hybrid Approach and current law. On the other hand, the X-tax would change current law significantly more than the Hybrid Approach, thereby exacerbating transition costs. Blending the respective strengths of the X-tax and the Hybrid Approach, I propose a new consumption tax consisting of three parts: a progressive wage tax, a business tax solely on corporations, and a limited individual tax on consumption less wages. This combination minimizes both individual tax reporting and changes to current law, thereby easing the way to a more equitable, efficient, and administrable tax system

    Sham on You: Too Good to Be True

    Get PDF
    Of course, many taxpayers manipulate their affairs to minimize their taxes. The new December 2017 limits on state tax deductions evidence, however, the more endemic nature of the sham problem. Some state government officials have joined the loophole quest on behalf of their citizens. For instance, some states have proposed new state tax credits for “voluntary” contributions to state charities. Treasury Secretary Mnuchin aptly challenged this “ridiculous” attempt to “dress up” non-deductible tax payments as deductible charitable contributions. Despite Mnuchin’s convincing rebuke, state officials carry on with their ongoing avoidance efforts. In addition, similar avoidance schemes permeate many other legal areas such as property law, contract law, family law, and copyright law. While some courts strike down the sham attempts, other courts are less vigilant. Occasionally, some courts even endorse the workaround to achieve a desired goal. How should the legal system respond to all these legal gymnastics? First, lawmakers should avoid even sanctioned indirect workarounds. Even though intended as a narrowly circumscribed allowance, these endorsed maneuvers foster disrespect for legal requirements and create an air of legitimacy for other unintended manipulations. Instead, lawmakers should endeavor to achieve their desired ends more directly, without resort to these problematic formalisms. Unsanctioned schemes present a more intricate challenge. After analyzing the reasons behind the current judicial inertia, this Article crafts a new sham defense system sensitive to the root causes. A precise, but limited, sham definition provides the first line of a defense against the most egregious cases. Next, a balanced summary judgment approach further reinforces the new sham definition. Finally, legislative recommendations for vulnerable provisions complete the necessary protection

    Not Too Separate or Unequal: Marriage Penalty Relief after \u3ci\u3eObergefell\u3c/i\u3e

    Get PDF
    Joint tax returns have generated controversy for many years. Married couples with the same joint income pay the same tax under our current system regardless of the earnings distribution between the spouses. This approach primarily rests on the idea that married couples share resources and operate as a single economic unit. Critics typically challenge this assumption and lament how marriage might significantly change a couple’s taxes. Depending on their earnings breakdown, a couple’s taxes could be reduced (a marital bonus for uneven-earners) or increased (a marital penalty for even-earners). These possibilities exist because the joint brackets are typically larger–but not twice as large–as the unmarried brackets. Recent Supreme Court decisions about same-sex marriage revitalize this debate since many same-sex couples face the marriage penalty. In response, some recent commentators propose the elimination of joint returns. However, such elimination faces serious roadblocks, including political concerns and tension with marriage’s collaborative character. While higher joint bracket allowances likewise would provide penalty relief, this would increase both marital bonuses and the associated revenue loss. We propose instead a unique solution to the current standstill: an option for married couples to calculate their tax on their separate earnings. These separate amounts would be combined on a joint return. The new separate brackets would be more than half the joint allowance but less than the singles cap. This range permits maximum flexibility to balance revenue concerns with other important values. Further, our approach would provide significant penalty relief without any undesired impact on bonuses. It also would maintain our deeply ingrained joint return system. Finally, we demonstrate the superiority of our proposal over other suggested compromises
    • …
    corecore