1,653 research outputs found
A model for correlations in stock markets
We propose a group model for correlations in stock markets. In the group
model the markets are composed of several groups, within which the stock price
fluctuations are correlated. The spectral properties of empirical correlation
matrices reported in [Phys. Rev. Lett. {\bf 83}, 1467 (1999); Phys. Rev. Lett.
{\bf 83}, 1471 (1999.)] are well understood from the model. It provides the
connection between the spectral properties of the empirical correlation matrix
and the structure of correlations in stock markets.Comment: two pages including one EPS file for a figur
Agents Play Mix-game
In mix-game which is an extension of minority game, there are two groups of
agents; group1 plays the majority game, but the group2 plays the minority game.
This paper studies the change of the average winnings of agents and
volatilities vs. the change of mixture of agents in mix-game model. It finds
that the correlations between the average winnings of agents and the mean of
local volatilities are different with different combinations of agent memory
length when the proportion of agents in group 1 increases. This study result
suggests that memory length of agents in group1 be smaller than that of agent
in group2 when mix-game model is used to simulate the financial markets.Comment: 8 pages, 6 figures, 3 table
Scaling of the distribution of fluctuations of financial market indices
We study the distribution of fluctuations over a time scale (i.e.,
the returns) of the S&P 500 index by analyzing three distinct databases.
Database (i) contains approximately 1 million records sampled at 1 min
intervals for the 13-year period 1984-1996, database (ii) contains 8686 daily
records for the 35-year period 1962-1996, and database (iii) contains 852
monthly records for the 71-year period 1926-1996. We compute the probability
distributions of returns over a time scale , where varies
approximately over a factor of 10^4 - from 1 min up to more than 1 month. We
find that the distributions for 4 days (1560 mins) are
consistent with a power-law asymptotic behavior, characterized by an exponent
, well outside the stable L\'evy regime . To
test the robustness of the S&P result, we perform a parallel analysis on two
other financial market indices. Database (iv) contains 3560 daily records of
the NIKKEI index for the 14-year period 1984-97, and database (v) contains 4649
daily records of the Hang-Seng index for the 18-year period 1980-97. We find
estimates of consistent with those describing the distribution of S&P
500 daily-returns. One possible reason for the scaling of these distributions
is the long persistence of the autocorrelation function of the volatility. For
time scales longer than days, our results are
consistent with slow convergence to Gaussian behavior.Comment: 12 pages in multicol LaTeX format with 27 postscript figures
(Submitted to PRE May 20, 1999). See
http://polymer.bu.edu/~amaral/Professional.html for more of our work on this
are
Universal and non-universal properties of cross-correlations in financial time series
We use methods of random matrix theory to analyze the cross-correlation
matrix C of price changes of the largest 1000 US stocks for the 2-year period
1994-95. We find that the statistics of most of the eigenvalues in the spectrum
of C agree with the predictions of random matrix theory, but there are
deviations for a few of the largest eigenvalues. We find that C has the
universal properties of the Gaussian orthogonal ensemble of random matrices.
Furthermore, we analyze the eigenvectors of C through their inverse
participation ratio and find eigenvectors with large inverse participation
ratios at both edges of the eigenvalue spectrum--a situation reminiscent of
results in localization theory.Comment: 14 pages, 3 figures, Revte
Statistical properties of absolute log-returns and a stochastic model of stock markets with heterogeneous agents
This paper is intended as an investigation of the statistical properties of
{\it absolute log-returns}, defined as the absolute value of the logarithmic
price change, for the Nikkei 225 index in the 28-year period from January 4,
1975 to December 30, 2002. We divided the time series of the Nikkei 225 index
into two periods, an inflationary period and a deflationary period. We have
previously [18] found that the distribution of absolute log-returns can be
approximated by the power-law distribution in the inflationary period, while
the distribution of absolute log-returns is well described by the exponential
distribution in the deflationary period.\par To further explore these empirical
findings, we have introduced a model of stock markets which was proposed in
[19,20]. In this model, the stock market is composed of two groups of traders:
{\it the fundamentalists}, who believe that the asset price will return to the
fundamental price, and {\it the interacting traders}, who can be noise traders.
We show through numerical simulation of the model that when the number of
interacting traders is greater than the number of fundamentalists, the
power-law distribution of absolute log-returns is generated by the interacting
traders' herd behavior, and, inversely, when the number of fundamentalists is
greater than the number of interacting traders, the exponential distribution of
absolute log-returns is generated.Comment: 12 pages, 5 figure
Scaling of the distribution of price fluctuations of individual companies
We present a phenomenological study of stock price fluctuations of individual
companies. We systematically analyze two different databases covering
securities from the three major US stock markets: (a) the New York Stock
Exchange, (b) the American Stock Exchange, and (c) the National Association of
Securities Dealers Automated Quotation stock market. Specifically, we consider
(i) the trades and quotes database, for which we analyze 40 million records for
1000 US companies for the 2-year period 1994--95, and (ii) the Center for
Research and Security Prices database, for which we analyze 35 million daily
records for approximately 16,000 companies in the 35-year period 1962--96. We
study the probability distribution of returns over varying time scales , where varies by a factor of ---from 5 min up to
4 years. For time scales from 5~min up to approximately 16~days, we
find that the tails of the distributions can be well described by a power-law
decay, characterized by an exponent ---well outside the
stable L\'evy regime . For time scales days, we observe results consistent with a slow
convergence to Gaussian behavior. We also analyze the role of cross
correlations between the returns of different companies and relate these
correlations to the distribution of returns for market indices.Comment: 10pages 2 column format with 11 eps figures. LaTeX file requiring
epsf, multicol,revtex. Submitted to PR
Statistical Properties of Share Volume Traded in Financial Markets
We quantitatively investigate the ideas behind the often-expressed adage `it
takes volume to move stock prices', and study the statistical properties of the
number of shares traded for a given stock in a fixed time
interval . We analyze transaction data for the largest 1000 stocks
for the two-year period 1994-95, using a database that records every
transaction for all securities in three major US stock markets. We find that
the distribution displays a power-law decay, and that the
time correlations in display long-range persistence. Further, we
investigate the relation between and the number of transactions
in a time interval , and find that the long-range
correlations in are largely due to those of . Our
results are consistent with the interpretation that the large equal-time
correlation previously found between and the absolute value of
price change (related to volatility) are largely due to
.Comment: 4 pages, two-column format, four figure
Statistical mechanics of the mixed majority-minority game with random external information
We study the asymptotic macroscopic properties of the mixed majority-minority
game, modeling a population in which two types of heterogeneous adaptive
agents, namely ``fundamentalists'' driven by differentiation and
``trend-followers'' driven by imitation, interact. The presence of a fraction f
of trend-followers is shown to induce (a) a significant loss of informational
efficiency with respect to a pure minority game (in particular, an efficient,
unpredictable phase exists only for f<1/2), and (b) a catastrophic increase of
global fluctuations for f>1/2. We solve the model by means of an approximate
static (replica) theory and by a direct dynamical (generating functional)
technique. The two approaches coincide and match numerical results
convincingly.Comment: 19 pages, 3 figure
- …