515 research outputs found
On CAPM and Black-Scholes, differing risk-return strategies
In their path-finding 1973 paper Black and Scholes presented two separate derivations of their famous option pricing partial differential equation (pde). The second derivation was from the standpoint that was Black’s original motivation, namely, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). We show here, in contrast, that the option valuation is not uniquely determined; in particular, strategies based on the delta-hedge and CAPM provide different valuations of an option although both hedges are instantaneouly riskfree. Second, we show explicitly that CAPM is not, as economists claim, an equilibrium theory.Capital asset pricing model (CAPM); nonequilibrium; financial markets; Black-Scholes; option pricing strategies;
An empirical model of volatility of returns and option pricing
This paper reports several entirely new results on financial market dynamics and option pricing We observe that empirical distributions of returns are much better approximated by an exponential distribution than by a Gaussian. This exponential distribution of asset prices can be used to develop a new pricing model for options (in closed algebraic form) that is shown to provide valuations that agree very well with those used by traders. We show how the Fokker-Planck formulation of fluctuations can be used with a local volatility (diffusion coeffficient) to generate an exponential distribution for asset returns, and also how fat tails for extreme returns are generated dynamically by a simple generalization of our new volatility model. Nonuniqueness in deducing dynamics from empirical data is discussed and is shown to have no practical effect over time scales much less than one hundred years. We derive an option pricing pde and explain why it‘s superfluous, because all information required to price options in agreement with the delta-hedge is already included in the Green function of the Fokker-Planck equation for a special choice of parameters. Finally, we also show how to calculate put and call prices for a stretched exponential returns density.Market instability; market dynamics; finance; option pricing
Martingales, the efficient market hypothesis, and spurious stylized facts
The condition for stationary increments, not scaling,
detemines long time pair autocorrelations. An incorrect
assumption of stationary increments generates spurious
stylized facts, fat tails and a Hurst exponent Hs=1/2, when
the increments are nonstationary, as they are in FX markets.
The nonstationarity arises from systematic uneveness in
noise traders’ behavior. Spurious results arise
mathematically from using a log increment with a ‘sliding
window’. We explain why a hard to beat market demands
martingale dynamics , and martingales with nonlinear
variance generate nonstationary increments. The
nonstationarity is exhibited directly for Euro/Dollar FX
data. We observe that the Hurst exponent Hs generated by
the using the sliding window technique on a time series
plays the same role as does Mandelbrot’s Joseph exponent.
Finally, Mandelbrot originally assumed that the ‘badly
behaved second moment of cotton returns is due to fat tails,
but that nonconvergent behavior is instead direct evidence
for nonstationary increments. Summarizing, the evidence for
scaling and fat tails as the basis for econophysics and
financial economics is provided neither by FX markets nor
by cotton price data
Martingale Option Pricing
We show that our generalization of the Black-Scholes partial differential
equation (pde) for nontrivial diffusion coefficients is equivalent to a
Martingale in the risk neutral discounted stock price. Previously, this was
proven for the case of the Gaussian logarithmic returns model by Harrison and
Kreps, but we prove it for much a much larger class of returns models where the
diffusion coefficient depends on both returns x and time t. That option prices
blow up if fat tails in logarithmic returns x are included in the market
dynamics is also explained
Nonstationary Increments, Scaling Distributions, and Variable Diffusion Processes in Financial Markets
Arguably the most important problem in quantitative finance is to understand
the nature of stochastic processes that underlie market dynamics. One aspect of
the solution to this problem involves determining characteristics of the
distribution of fluctuations in returns. Empirical studies conducted over the
last decade have reported that they arenon-Gaussian, scale in time, and have
power-law(or fat) tails. However, because they use sliding interval methods of
analysis, these studies implicitly assume that the underlying process has
stationary increments. We explicitly show that this assumption is not valid for
the Euro-Dollar exchange rate between 1999-2004. In addition, we find that
fluctuations in returns of the exchange rate are uncorrelated and scale as
power-laws for certain time intervals during each day. This behavior is
consistent with a diffusive process with a diffusion coefficient that depends
both on the time and the price change. Within scaling regions, we find that
sliding interval methods can generate fat-tailed distributions as an artifact,
and that the type of scaling reported in many previous studies does not exist.Comment: 12 pages, 4 figure
Nonstationary increments, scaling distributions, and variable diffusion processes in financial markets
Arguably the most important problem in quantitative finance is to understand the nature of stochastic processes that underlie market dynamics. One aspect of the solution to this problem involves determining characteristics of the distribution of fluctuations in returns. Empirical studies conducted over the last decade have reported that they are non-Gaussian, scale in time, and have power-law (or fat) tails [1–5]. However, because they use sliding interval methods of analysis, these studies implicitly assume that the underlying process has stationary increments. We explicitly show that this assumption is not valid for the Euro-Dollar exchange rate between 1999-2004. In addition, we find that fluctuations in returns of the exchange rate are uncorrelated and scale as power laws for certain time intervals during each day. This behavior is consistent with a diffusive process with a diffusion coefficient that depends both on the time and the price change. Within scaling regions, we find that sliding interval methods can generate fat-tailed distributions as an artifact, and that the type of scaling reported in many previous studies does not exist.Nonstationary increments; autocorrelations; scaling; Hurst exponents; Markov process
Hurst exponents, Markov processes, and nonlinear diffusion equations
We show by explicit closed form calculations that a Hurst exponent H≠1/2 does not necessarily imply long time correlations like those found in fractional Brownian motion. We construct a large set of scaling solutions of Fokker-Planck partial differential equations where H≠1/2. Thus Markov processes, which by construction have no long time correlations, can have H≠1/2. If a Markov process scales with Hurst exponent H≠1/2 then it simply means that the process has nonstationary increments. For the scaling solutions, we show how to reduce the calculation of the probability density to a single integration once the diffusion coefficient D(x,t) is specified. As an example, we generate a class of student-t-like densities from the class of quadratic diffusion coefficients. Notably, the Tsallis density is one member of that large class. The Tsallis density is usually thought to result from a nonlinear diffusion equation, but instead we explicitly show that it follows from a Markov process generated by a linear Fokker-Planck equation, and therefore from a corresponding Langevin equation. Having a Tsallis density with H≠1/2 therefore does not imply dynamics with correlated signals, e.g., like those of fractional Brownian motion. A short review of the requirements for fractional Brownian motion is given for clarity, and we explain why the usual simple argument that H≠1/2 implies correlations fails for Markov processes with scaling solutions. Finally, we discuss the question of scaling of the full Green function g(x,t;x',t') of the Fokker-Planck pde.Hurst exponent; Markov process; scaling; stochastic calculus; autocorrelations; fractional Brownian motion; Tsallis model; nonlinear diffusion
Rhombic Patterns: Broken Hexagonal Symmetry
Landau-Ginzburg equations derived to conserve two-dimensional spatial symmetries lead to the prediction that rhombic arrays with characteristic angles slightly differ from 60 degrees should form in many systems. Beyond the bifurcation from the uniform state to patterns, rhombic patterns are linearly stable for a band of angles near the 60 degrees angle of regular hexagons. Experiments conducted on a reaction-diffusion system involving a chlorite-iodide-malonic acid reaction yield rhombic patterns in good accord with the theory.Energy Laboratory of the University of HoustonOffice of Naval ResearchU.S. Department of Energy Office of Basic Energy SciencesRobert A. Welch FoundationCenter for Nonlinear Dynamic
- …