30,900 research outputs found
Intersection theory and the Alesker product
Alesker has introduced the space of {\it smooth
valuations} on a smooth manifold , and shown that it admits a natural
commutative multiplication. Although Alesker's original construction is highly
technical, from a moral perspective this product is simply an artifact of the
operation of intersection of two sets. Subsequently Alesker and Bernig gave an
expression for the product in terms of differential forms. We show how the
Alesker-Bernig formula arises naturally from the intersection interpretation,
and apply this insight to give a new formula for the product of a general
valuation with a valuation that is expressed in terms of intersections with a
sufficiently rich family of smooth polyhedra.Comment: further revisons, now 23 page
Convolution of convex valuations
We show that the natural "convolution" on the space of smooth, even,
translation-invariant convex valuations on a euclidean space , obtained by
intertwining the product and the duality transform of S. Alesker, may be
expressed in terms of Minkowski sum. Furthermore the resulting product extends
naturally to odd valuations as well. Based on this technical result we give an
application to integral geometry, generalizing Hadwiger's additive kinematic
formula for to general compact groups acting
transitively on the sphere: it turns out that these formulas are in a natural
sense dual to the usual (intersection) kinematic formulas.Comment: 18 pages; Thm. 1.4. added; references updated; other minor changes;
to appear in Geom. Dedicat
Riemannian curvature measures
A famous theorem of Weyl states that if is a compact submanifold of
euclidean space, then the volumes of small tubes about are given by a
polynomial in the radius , with coefficients that are expressible as
integrals of certain scalar invariants of the curvature tensor of with
respect to the induced metric. It is natural to interpret this phenomenon in
terms of curvature measures and smooth valuations, in the sense of Alesker,
canonically associated to the Riemannian structure of . This perspective
yields a fundamental new structure in Riemannian geometry, in the form of a
certain abstract module over the polynomial algebra that
reflects the behavior of Alesker multiplication. This module encodes a key
piece of the array of kinematic formulas of any Riemannian manifold on which a
group of isometries acts transitively on the sphere bundle. We illustrate this
principle in precise terms in the case where is a complex space form.Comment: Corrected version, to appear in GAF
Optimal sampling strategies for multiscale stochastic processes
In this paper, we determine which non-random sampling of fixed size gives the
best linear predictor of the sum of a finite spatial population. We employ
different multiscale superpopulation models and use the minimum mean-squared
error as our optimality criterion. In multiscale superpopulation tree models,
the leaves represent the units of the population, interior nodes represent
partial sums of the population, and the root node represents the total sum of
the population. We prove that the optimal sampling pattern varies dramatically
with the correlation structure of the tree nodes. While uniform sampling is
optimal for trees with ``positive correlation progression'', it provides the
worst possible sampling with ``negative correlation progression.'' As an
analysis tool, we introduce and study a class of independent innovations trees
that are of interest in their own right. We derive a fast water-filling
algorithm to determine the optimal sampling of the leaves to estimate the root
of an independent innovations tree.Comment: Published at http://dx.doi.org/10.1214/074921706000000509 in the IMS
Lecture Notes--Monograph Series
(http://www.imstat.org/publications/lecnotes.htm) by the Institute of
Mathematical Statistics (http://www.imstat.org
Labor Supply Preferences, Hours Constraints, and Hours-Wage Tradeoffs
In a labor market in which firms offer tied hours-wage packages and there is substantial dispersion in the wage offers associated with a particular type of job, the best job available to a worker at a point in time may pay well but require an hours level which is far from the worker's labor supply schedule, or pay poorly but offer desirable hours. Intuitively, one would expect hours constraints to influence the pattern of wage-hours tradeoffs which occur when workers quit to new jobs. Constrained workers may be willing to sacrifice wage gains for better hours. Likewise, workers may accept jobs offering undesirable hours only if the associated wage gains are large. We investigate this issue empirically by examining whether overemployment (underemployment) on the initial job increases (reduces) the partial effect on the wage gain of a positive change in hours for those who quit. We also examine whether overemployment (underemployment) on the new job increases (reduces) the partial effect on the wage gain of a positive change in hours for those who quit. Despite the limitations imposed by small sample sizes and lack of information on the magnitude of hours constraints, our results support the view that an individual requires compensation to work in jobs which, given the individual's particular preferences, offer unattractive hours.
- …