243 research outputs found
Thinking about Attention in Games: Backward and Forward Induction
Behavioral economics improves economic analysis by using psychological
regularity to suggest limits on rationality and self-interest (e.g. Camerer and
Loewenstein 2003). Expressing these regularities in formal terms permits productive
theorizing, suggests new experiments, can contribute to psychology,
and can be used to shape economic policies which make normal people
better off
Learning and Visceral Temptation in Dynamic Saving Experiments
This paper tests two explanations for apparent undersaving in life cycle models: bounded rationality and a preference for immediacy. Each was addressed in a separate experimental study. In the first study, subjects saved too little initiallyâproviding evidence for bounded rationalityâbut learned to save optimally within four repeated life cycles. In the second study, thirsty subjects who consume beverage sips immediately, rather than with a delay, show greater relative overspending, consistent with quasi-hyperbolic discounting models. The parameter estimates of overspending obtained from the second study, but not the first, are in range of several empirical studies of saving (with an estimated ÎČ = 0.6â0.7)
Learning and Visceral Temptation in Dynamic Savings Experiments
In models of optimal savings with income uncertainty and habit formation, people
should save early to create a buffer stock, to cushion bad income draws and limit
the negative internality from habit formation. In experiments in this setting,
people save too little initially, but learn to save optimally within four repeated
lifecycles, or 1-2 lifecycles with âsocial learning.â Using beverage rewards (cola)
to create visceral temptation, thirsty subjects who consume immediately
overspend compared to subjects who only drink after time delay. The relative
overspending of immediate-consumption subjects is consistent with hyperbolic
discounting and dual-self models. Estimates of the present-bias choices are
ÎČ=0.6-0.7, which are consistent with other studies (albeit over different time
horizons)
Cognition and framing in sequential bargaining for gains and losses
Noncooperative game-theoretic models of sequential bargaining give an
underpinning to cooperative solution concepts derived from axioms, and
have proved useful in applications (see Osborne and Rubinstein 1990). But
experimental studies of sequential bargaining with discounting have generally
found systematic deviations between the offers people make and perfect
equilibrium offers derived from backward induction (e.g., Ochs and
Roth 1989).
We have extended this experimental literature in two ways. First,
we used a novel software system to record the information subjects
looked at while they bargained. Measuring patterns of information search
helped us draw inferences about how people think, testing as directly
as possible whether people use backward induction to compute offers.
Second, we compared bargaining over gains that shrink over time (because
of discounting) to equivalent bargaining over losses that expand over
time.
In the games we studied, two players bargain by making a finite number
of alternating offers. A unique subgame-perfect equilibrium can be computed
by backward induction. The induction begins in the last period and
works forward. Our experiments use a three-round game with a pie of
2.50 and
1.25 and keeps $3.75
The process-performance paradox in expert judgment - How can experts know so much and predict so badly?
A mysterious fatal disease strikes a large minority of the population.
The disease is incurable, but an expensive drug can keep victims alive. Congress decides that the drug should be given to those whose lives can be
extended longest, which only a few specialists can predict. The experts work
around the clock searching for a cure; allocating the drug is a new chore they
would rather avoid
Detecting Failures of Backward Induction: Monitoring Information Search in Sequential Bargaining
We did experiments in a three-round bargaining game where the (perfect) equilibrium offer was 2.50. The average offer was 2.11
Detecting Failures of Backward Induction: Monitoring Information Search in Sequential Bargaining
We ran three-round sequential bargaining experiments in which the perfect equilibrium offer was 2.50. Subjects offered 1.84 to ârobotâ players (who are known to play subgame perfectly), and $1.22 to robots after instruction in backward induction. Measures of information search showed that subjects did not look at the amounts being divided in different rounds in the correct order, and for the length of time, necessary for backward induction, unless they were specifically instructed. The results suggest that most of the departure from perfect equilibrium is due to limited computation and some is due to fairness
Cytoprotective Activated Protein C Averts Nlrp3 InflammasomeâInduced Ischemia-Reperfusion Injury Via Mtorc1 Inhibition
Cytoprotection by activated protein C (aPC) after ischemia-reperfusion injury (IRI) is associated with apoptosis inhibition. However, IRI is hallmarked by inflammation, and hence, cell-death forms disjunct from immunologically silent apoptosis are, in theory, more likely to be relevant. Because pyroptosis (ie, cell death resulting from inflammasome activation) is typically observed in IRI, we speculated that aPC ameliorates IRI by inhibiting inflammasome activation. Here we analyzed the impact of aPC on inflammasome activity in myocardial and renal IRIs. aPC treatment before or after myocardial IRI reduced infarct size and Nlrp3 inflammasome activation in mice. Kinetic in vivo analyses revealed that Nlrp3 inflammasome activation preceded myocardial injury and apoptosis, corroborating a pathogenic role of the Nlrp3 inflammasome. The constitutively active Nlrp3A350V mutation abolished the protective effect of aPC, demonstrating that Nlrp3 suppression is required for aPC-mediated protection from IRI. In vitro aPC inhibited inflammasome activation in macrophages, cardiomyocytes, and cardiac fibroblasts via proteinase-activated receptor 1 (PAR-1) and mammalian target of rapamycin complex 1 (mTORC1) signaling. Accordingly, inhibiting PAR-1 signaling, but not the anticoagulant properties of aPC, abolished the ability of aPC to restrict Nlrp3 inflammasome activity and tissue damage in myocardial IRI. Targeting biased PAR-1 signaling via parmodulin-2 restricted mTORC1 and Nlrp3 inflammasome activation and limited myocardial IRI as efficiently as aPC. The relevance of aPC-mediated Nlrp3 inflammasome suppression after IRI was corroborated in renal IRI, where the tissue protective effect of aPC was likewise dependent on Nlrp3 inflammasome suppression. These studies reveal that aPC protects from IRI by restricting mTORC1-dependent inflammasome activation and that mimicking biased aPC PAR-1 signaling using parmodulins may be a feasible therapeutic approach to combat IRI
PAR2 (protease-activated receptor 2) Deficiency Attenuates Atherosclerosis in Mice
Objective-PAR2 (protease-activated receptor 2)-dependent signaling results in augmented inflammation and has been implicated in the pathogenesis of several autoimmune conditions. The objective of this study was to determine the effect of PAR2 deficiency on the development of atherosclerosis. Approach and Resutle-PAR2 mRNA and protein expression is increased in human carotid artery and mouse aortic arch atheroma versus control carotid and aortic arch arteries, respectively. To determine the effect of PAR2 deficiency on atherosclerosis, male and female low-density lipoprotein receptor-deficient (Ldlr-/-) mice (8-12 weeks old) that were Par2+/+ or Par2-/- were fed a fat-and cholesterol-enriched diet for 12 or 24 weeks. PAR2 deficiency attenuated atherosclerosis in the aortic sinus and aortic root after 12 and 24 weeks. PAR2 deficiency did not alter total plasma cholesterol concentrations or lipoprotein distributions. Bone marrow transplantation showed that PAR2 on nonhematopoietic cells contributed to atherosclerosis. PAR2 deficiency significantly attenuated levels of the chemokines Ccl2 and Cxcl1 in the circulation and macrophage content in atherosclerotic lesions. Mechanistic studies using isolated primary vascular smooth muscle cells showed that PAR2 deficiency is associated with reduced Ccl2 and Cxcl1 mRNA expression and protein release into the supernatant resulting in less monocyte migration.Conclusion-Our results indicate that PAR2 deficiency is associated with attenuation of atherosclerosis and may reduce lesion progression by blunting Ccl2-and Cxcl1-induced monocyte infiltration
PAR2 absence completely rescues inflammation and ichthyosis caused by altered CAP1/Prss8 expression in mouse skin
Altered serine protease activity is associated with skin disorders in humans and in mice. The serine protease channel-activating protease-1 (CAP1; also termed protease serine S1 family member 8 (Prss8)) is important for epidermal homeostasis and is thus indispensable for postnatal survival in mice, but its roles and effectors in skin pathology are poorly defined. In this paper, we report that transgenic expression in mouse skin of either CAP1/Prss8 (K14-CAP1/Prss8) or protease-activated receptor-2 (PAR2; Grhl3PAR2/+), one candidate downstream target, causes epidermal hyperplasia, ichthyosis and itching. K14-CAP1/Prss8 ectopic expression impairs epidermal barrier function and causes skin inflammation characterized by an increase in thymic stromal lymphopoietin levels and immune cell infiltrations. Strikingly, both gross and functional K14-CAP1/Prss8-induced phenotypes are completely negated when superimposed on a PAR2-null background, establishing PAR2 as a pivotal mediator of pathogenesis. Our data provide genetic evidence for PAR2 as a downstream effector of CAP1/Prss8 in a signalling cascade that may provide novel therapeutic targets for ichthyoses, pruritus and inflammatory skin diseases
- âŠ