2,172 research outputs found
Algebraic Properties of BRST Coupled Doublets
We characterize the dependence on doublets of the cohomology of an arbitrary
nilpotent differential s (including BRST differentials and classical linearized
Slavnov-Taylor (ST) operators) in terms of the cohomology of the
doublets-independent component of s. All cohomologies are computed in the space
of local integrated formal power series. We drop the usual assumption that the
counting operator for the doublets commutes with s (decoupled doublets) and
discuss the general case where the counting operator does not commute with s
(coupled doublets). The results are purely algebraic and do not rely on
power-counting arguments.Comment: Some explanations enlarged, references adde
Background gauge invariance in the antifield formalism for theories with open gauge algebras
We show that any BRST invariant quantum action with open or closed gauge
algebra has a corresponding local background gauge invariance. If the BRST
symmetry is anomalous, but the anomaly can be removed in the antifield
formalism, then the effective action possesses a local background gauge
invariance. The presence of antifields (BRST sources) is necessary. As an
example we analyze chiral gravity.Comment: 17pp., Latex, mispelling in my name! corrected, no other change
O clima da regiĂŁo de Dourados, MS.
O Clima da RegiĂŁo de Dourados, MS; AnĂĄlise dos Principais Elementos MeteorolĂłgicos; Temperatura e umidade relativa do ar; Insolação e fotoperĂodo; Vento; Evapotranspiração; Chuva; Veranicos e estiagens; Balanço hĂdrico; OcorrĂȘncia de Geadas; Classificação climĂĄtica.bitstream/item/37989/1/DOC200892.pdf2. ed.1. ed. disponĂvel apenas on-line
Power-law correlations and orientational glass in random-field Heisenberg models
Monte Carlo simulations have been used to study a discretized Heisenberg
ferromagnet (FM) in a random field on simple cubic lattices. The spin variable
on each site is chosen from the twelve [110] directions. The random field has
infinite strength and a random direction on a fraction x of the sites of the
lattice, and is zero on the remaining sites. For x = 0 there are two phase
transitions. At low temperatures there is a [110] FM phase, and at intermediate
temperature there is a [111] FM phase. For x > 0 there is an intermediate phase
between the paramagnet and the ferromagnet, which is characterized by a
|k|^(-3) decay of two-spin correlations, but no true FM order. The [111] FM
phase becomes unstable at a small value of x. At x = 1/8 the [110] FM phase has
disappeared, but the power-law correlated phase survives.Comment: 8 pages, 12 Postscript figure
Attorneys as Arbitrators
We study the role of attorneys as arbitrators in securities arbitration conducted by the National Association of Securities Dealers (NASD, n/k/a FINRA), using a dataset of 422 randomly selected arbitrators and their 6724 arbitration awards from 1992 to 2006. We find that arbitrators who also represent brokerage firms or brokers in other arbitrations award significantly less compensation to investor-claimants than other arbitrators. We find no significant effect for attorney-arbitrators who represent investors or both investors and brokerage firms. The relation between representing brokerage firms and arbitration awards remains significant even when we control for political outlook. We report that ideology correlates significantly with arbitration awards â arbitrators who donate money to Democratic political candidates award greater compensation than arbitrators who donate to Republican candidates.
Because the arbitration award is the product of the panel, not a single arbitrator, we also study the dynamics of panel interaction. We find that the position of chair is an important factor in assessing the arbitratorâs influence, although the financial relationships of other arbitrators may also affect arbitration awards. Coalitions with the other arbitrators are also important. If the chair and another panelist possess a common attribute, the effect on the arbitration award increases.
Finally, we provide evidence that the 1998 reforms to the arbitration process â which introduced party control over the composition of panels â ameliorated, but did not eliminate, the effect that attorneys who represent brokers have on outcomes. We find no significant effect from the NASDâs 2004 reforms
Subextensive singularity in the 2D Ising spin glass
The statistics of low energy states of the 2D Ising spin glass with +1 and -1
bonds are studied for square lattices with , and =
0.5, where is the fraction of negative bonds, using periodic and/or
antiperiodic boundary conditions. The behavior of the density of states near
the ground state energy is analyzed as a function of , in order to obtain
the low temperature behavior of the model. For large finite there is a
range of in which the heat capacity is proportional to .
The range of in which this behavior occurs scales slowly to as
increases. Similar results are found for = 0.25. Our results indicate that
this model probably obeys the ordinary hyperscaling relation , even though . The existence of the subextensive behavior is
attributed to long-range correlations between zero-energy domain walls, and
evidence of such correlations is presented.Comment: 13 pages, 7 figures; final version, to appear in J. Stat. Phy
Development of high temperature oxidation resistant coatings for chromium-base alloys Final report
High temperature oxidation resistant coatings for chromium-base alloy
Do Institutions Matter? The Impact of the Lead Plaintiff Provision of the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act
When Congress enacted the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act in 1995 (âPSLRAâ), the Actâs âlead plaintiffâ provision was the centerpiece of its efforts to increase investor control over securities fraud class actions. The lead plaintiff provision alters the balance of power between investors and class counsel by creating a presumption that the investor with the largest financial stake in the case will serve as lead plaintiff. The lead plaintiff then chooses class counsel and, at least in theory, negotiates the terms of counselâs compensation.
Congressâs stated purpose in enacting the lead plaintiff provision was to encourage institutional investorsâpension funds, mutual funds, hedge funds, etc.âto come forward to serve as lead plaintiff. The theory was that an institutional investor with a substantial damages claim would have the incentive to bargain hard with class counsel on behalf of the class, reducing the percentage of the recovery awarded to class counsel. Congress also expected institutions to play an oversight role, monitoring to make sure that class counsel was vigorously pursuing claims on behalf of the class and not settling claims on the cheap.
Our study offers evidence on the extent to which the lead plaintiff provision furthers these goals. We have collected two samples of securities class actionsâone from 1991 to 1995 (pre-PSLRA) and one from 1996 to 2000 (post-PSLRA). We compare the class representatives from the two periods to determine if institutional investors are stepping forward in significantly greater numbers. We also sort the institutional investorsâdistinguishing public from privateâto see what types of investors have stepped forward to serve as lead plaintiff. Consistent with other research, we find a significant difference only in the number of public institutions serving as lead plaintiff.
Our sample also allows us to analyze the impact of the lead plaintiff provision: Does the presence of an institutional investor increase the likelihood of a high-value settlement? Despite the visible participation of institutions in several high-profile cases, we find no systematic evidence that private institutional lead plaintiffs are associated with larger class recoveries. Public pension fund lead plaintiffs, on the other hand, are correlated with higher class recoveries as a fraction of the potential damage award in the post-PSLRA period. Our results are, however, consistent with the possibility that public pensions âcherry-pickâ the actions in which they seek to become lead plaintiff, selecting only the cases with the largest potential damages and the strongest evidence of fraud. Further analysis is needed to evaluate this possibility.
We also evaluate the effect of lead plaintiffs on the selection of attorneys and attorneysâ fees. We find that, for the time period of our study, institutional investors tended to avoid the Milberg Weiss plaintiffsâ attorney firm. On the more fundamental issue of whether the presence of an institutional investor as a lead plaintiff reduces the fees paid to the lawyers, after controlling for the size of the case, we find no systematic evidence that institutional involvement correlates with lower fee awards
- âŠ