679 research outputs found

    The Return to Schooling in Structural Dynamic Models: A Survey

    Get PDF
    This papers contains a survey of the recent literature devoted to the returns to schooling within a dynamic structural framework. I present a historical perspective on the evolution of the literature, from early static models set in a selectivity framework (Willis and Rosen, 1979) to the recent literature, stimulated by Keane and Wolpin (1997), and which uses stochastic dynamic programming techniques. After reviewing the literature thoroughly, I compare the structural approach with the IV (experimental) approach. I present their commonalities and I also discuss their fundamental differences. To get an order of magnitude, most structural estimates reported for the US range between 4% and 7% per year. On the other hand, IV estimates between 10% and 15% per year are often reported. The discrepancy prevails even when comparable (if not identical) data sets are used. The discussion is focussed on understanding this divergence. The distinction between static and dynamic model speciïŹcations is a recurrent theme in the analysis. I argue that the distinction between the IV approach and the structural approach may be coined in terms of a trade off between behavioral and statistical assumptions. For this reason, and unless one has very speciïŹc knowledge of the true data generating process, it is neither possible, nor sensible, to claim which approach to estimation is more ïŹ‚exible. More precisely, I show that structural and IV approaches differ mainly at the level of i) the compatibility of the underlying models with truly dynamic behavior, ii) the role of heterogeneity in ability and tastes, iii) the consideration of post-schooling opportunities, and (iv) the speciïŹcation (and interpretation) of the Mincer wage equation.Returns to Schooling ; Human Capital ; Ability Bias ; Dynamic Programming ; Dynamic Self-Selection ; Natural experiments ; IV estimation

    Can Risk Aversion Explain Schooling Attainments?: evidence from Italy

    Get PDF
    Using unique Italian panel data, in which individual differences in behavior toward risk are measured from answers to a lottery question, we investigate if (and to what extent) risk aversion can explain differences in schooling attainments. We formulate the schooling decision process as a reduced-form dynamic discrete choice. The model is estimated with a degree of ïŹ‚exibility virtually compatible with semi- parametric likelihood techniques. We analyze how grade transition from one level to the next varies with preference heterogeneity (risk aversion), parental human capital, socioeconomic variables and persistent unobserved (to the econometrician) heterogeneity. We present evidence that schooling attainments decrease with risk aversion, but despite a statistically signiïŹcant effect, differences in attitudes toward risk account for a modest portion of the probability of entering higher education. Differences in ability(ies) and in parental human capital are much more important. in the most general version of the model, the likelihood function is the joint probability of schooling attainments, and post-schooling wealth and risk aversion.dynamic discrete choices ; education ; human capital ; risk aversion

    Promotions, Demotions, Halo Effects and Earnings Dynamics of American Executives

    Get PDF
    This paper explores the dynamics of wage growth in corporate hierarchies. Using panel data techniques, we estimate the causal effect of current and past transitions in reporting level and past earnings growth on components of current earnings and earnings growth using a large panel of US executives. After conditioning on unobserved heterogeneity, current compensation growth is positively correlated with past promotion outcomes but negatively correlated with past compensation growth. In a flexible model of wage growth, there is an important asymmetry between the effect of a promotion and a demotion. The effect of promotion is smaller in magnitude than the effect of a demotion. The causal effect of a promotion is positive on both growth in base pay and total cash compensation but is negative on bonus growth. The effect of a demotion is negative on growth in all pay components.earning growth ; promotion ; reputation

    Risk Aversion and Schooling Decisions

    Get PDF
    We develop a non-rational expectation econometric model of sequential schooling decisions. Using unique Italian panel data in which individual differences in attitudes toward risk are measurable (with error), we investigate the effect of risk aversion on the probability of entering higher education. This allows us to characterize the subjective (as opposed to the objective) effect of higher education on marginal risk exposure. Because the measure of risk aversion (the classical Arrow-Pratt degree of absolute risk aversion) is posterior to schooling decisions, it depends on current wealth realizations and we must therefore take into account its endogeneity. We also allow risk aversion to be measured with error. After taking into account both the endogeneity of wealth and measurement error, we find that risk aversion is a key determinant (comparable to parents' educational background) of the decisions to enter higher education. Precisely, risk aversion acts as a deterrent to higher education investmentdynamic discrete choices, Ă©ducation, ex-ante risk, risk aversion

    Earnings Dispersion, Risk Aversion and Education

    Get PDF
    We estimate a dynamic programming model of schooling decisions in which the degree of risk aversion can be inferred from schooling decisions. In our model, individuals are heterogeneous with respect to school and market abilities but homogeneous with respect to the degree of risk aversion. We allow endogenous schooling attainments to affect the level of risk experienced in labor market earnings through wage dispersion and employment rate dispersion. We find a low degree of relative risk aversion (0.93) and the estimates indicate that both wage and employment rate dispersions decrease significantly with schooling attainments. We find that a counterfactual increase in risk aversion will increase schooling attainments. Finally, the low degree of risk aversion implies that an increase in earnings dispersion would have little effect on schooling attainments.dynamic programming; earnings dispersion; human capital; returns to education; risk aversion

    Education and Early Career Outcomes of Second-Generation Immigrants in France

    Get PDF
    We estimate a flexible dynamic model of education choices and early career employment outcomes of the French population. Individuals are allowed to choose between 4 options: continue to the next grade, accept a permanent contract, accept a temporary contract, or withdraw from the labor force (a residual state). Our analysis focuses on the comparison between French Second-Generation Immigrants whose parents are born in Africa and French-natives. We find that schooling attainments explain around two thirds of the differences in access to early career employment stability. However, one third cannot be linked to observed investment in human capital.Second-generation immigrants ; schooling attainments ; fixed term employment

    The Promotion Dynamics of American Executives

    Get PDF
    We formulate an empirical model of promotion with dynamic selfselection where the current promotion probability depends on the hierarchical level in the firm, individual human capital, unobserved (to the econometrician) individual specific attributes, time varying firm specific variables (firm size and profits) as well as endogenous past promotion histories. We examine the causal effect of previous promotion histories (as measured by realized speed of promotion) on future promotion outcomes. The model is fit on an 8 year panel of promotion histories of 30,000 American executives employed in more than 380 different firms. The stochastic process generating promotions is weakly correlated with standard human capital endowment variables (age, schooling and tenure). It may be viewed as a series of promotion probabilities which become smaller as an individual moves up in the hierarchy and is primarily explained by individual (or firm) specific factors other than measured human capital. We also find that, conditional on unobservables, the promotion probability is only mildly enhanced, on average, by the speed of promotion achieved in the past (a structural fast track effect). However, we find the existence of a relatively high cross-sectional dispersion in the effect of past promotion histories and we are able to provide an explanation for this relatively high dispersion. In general, the magnitude of the individual specific effect of achieved speed of promotion is inversely related to accumulated human capital (schooling and tenure). We believe that these findings are consistent with the hypothesis that the signaling aspect of past promotions is stronger for those who are less educated and stronger for those who are relatively new in a firm. We also find that a negative correlation between current promotion and past speed of promotion cannot be ruled out for a portion of the population, and we are able to relate this finding to the “Peter Principle”.dynamic discrete choices; personnel economics; promotions

    The Promotion Dynamics of American Executives

    Get PDF
    We formulate an empirical model of promotion with dynamic selfselection where the current promotion probability depends on the hierarchical level in the firm, individual human capital, unobserved (to the econometrician) individual specific attributes, time varying firm specific variables (firm size and profits) as well as endogenous past promotion histories. We examine the causal effect of previous promotion histories (as measured by realized speed of promotion) on future promotion outcomes. The model is fit on an 8 year panel of promotion histories of 30,000 American executives employed in more than 380 different firms. The stochastic process generating promotions is weakly correlated with standard human capital endowment variables (age, schooling and tenure). It may be viewed as a series of promotion probabilities which become smaller as an individual moves up in the hierarchy and is primarily explained by individual (or firm) specific factors other than measured human capital. We also find that, conditional on unobservables, the promotion probability is only mildly enhanced, on average, by the speed of promotion achieved in the past (a structural fast track effect). However, we find the existence of a relatively high cross-sectional dispersion in the effect of past promotion histories and we are able to provide an explanation for this relatively high dispersion. In general, the magnitude of the individual specific effect of achieved speed of promotion is inversely related to accumulated human capital (schooling and tenure). We believe that these findings are consistent with the hypothesis that the signaling aspect of past promotions is stronger for those who are less educated and stronger for those who are relatively new in a firm. We also find that a negative correlation between current promotion and past speed of promotion cannot be ruled out for a portion of the population, and we are able to relate this finding to the "Peter Principle". Dans ce papier, nous estimons un modĂšle dynamique de promotion oĂč la notion d'effet causal (causal fast track) est diffĂ©renciĂ©e de la notion non-causale (spurious fast track). La probabilitĂ© de promotion est fonction du niveau hiĂ©rarchique dans la firme, des attributs observables et non observables des individus, des attributs observables (et dynamiques) de la firme (tels que les profits et la taille), ainsi que de l'historique (endogĂšne) des promotions passĂ©es mesurĂ© par la rapiditĂ© moyenne de promotion. Le modĂšle est appliquĂ© Ă  un Ă©chantillon de 30 000 cadres du secteur privĂ© amĂ©ricain, travaillant pour plus de 380 grandes firmes. Les rĂ©sultats indiquent que le processus alĂ©atoire gĂ©nĂ©rant les promotions dĂ©pend faiblement du niveau de capital humain, et trĂšs peu de la vitesse passĂ©e, mais beaucoup plus des facteurs non observables tels que la motivation. Les rĂ©sultats montrent Ă©galement qu'il y a une large dispersion dans l'effet de la vitesse de promotion sur les promotions futures. Bien que l'effet soit positif en moyenne, il est nĂ©gatif pour une sous-population. De façon gĂ©nĂ©rale, l'effet de la vitesse passĂ©e dĂ©croĂźt avec le niveau de capital humain et l'anciennetĂ© dans la firme. L'effet nĂ©gatif de la vitesse de promotion est compatible avec le "principe de Peter", souvent mentionnĂ© dans la littĂ©rature sur la dynamique des promotions.personnel economics, promotions, dynamic discrete choices, random effects, promotions, tournois, choix discrets dynamiques, Ă©conomie des ressources humaines, effets alĂ©atoires

    Education and Early Career Outcomes of Second-Generation Immigrants in France

    Get PDF
    We estimate a flexible dynamic model of education choices and early career employment outcomes of the French population. Individuals are allowed to choose between 4 options: continue to the next grade, accept a permanent contract, accept a temporary contract, or withdraw from the labor force (a residual state). Our analysis focuses on the comparison between French Second-Generation Immigrants whose parents are born in Africa and French-natives. We find that schooling attainments explain around two thirds of the differences in access to early career employment stability. However, one third cannot be linked to observed investment in human capital.schooling attainments, second-generation immigrants, fixed term employment

    Unobserved Ability and the Return to Schooling

    Get PDF
    We estimate a structural dynamic programming model of schooling decisions with unobserved heterogeneity in school ability and market ability on a sample taken from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY). Both the instantaneous utility of attending school and the wage regression function are estimated flexibly. The null hypothesis that the local returns to schooling are constant is strongly rejected in favor of a convex wage regression function composed of 8 spline segments. The local returns are very low until grade 11 (1% per year or less), increase to 3.7% in grade 12 and exceed 10% only from grade 14 to grade 16. The average return increases smoothly from 0.4% (grade 7) to 4.6% (grade 16). The convexity of the log wage regression function implies that those who obtain more schooling also experience higher average returns. We strongly reject the null hypothesis that unobserved market ability is uncorrelated with realized schooling attainments, which underlies many previous studies that have used OLS to estimate the return to schooling. The correlation between realized schooling and market ability is found to be positive and is consistent with the existence of a positive "Ability Bias". À partir d'un Ă©chantillon tirĂ© du National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY), nous estimons un modĂšle de programmation dynamique des choix d'Ă©ducation en prĂ©sence d'hĂ©tĂ©rogĂ©nĂ©itĂ© non observĂ©e dans les capacitĂ©s scolaires et aptitudes sur le marchĂ© de l'emploi. L'utilitĂ© instantanĂ©e de la frĂ©quentation scolaire ainsi que la fonction de salaire sont Ă©valuĂ©es de façon flexible. L'hypothĂšse nulle que les rendements marginaux de l'Ă©ducation sont constants est catĂ©goriquement rejetĂ©e en faveur d'une fonction de salaire convexe composĂ©e de huit segments de fonction d'approximation spline. Les rendements marginaux s'avĂšrent ĂȘtre trĂšs faibles jusqu'Ă  la onziĂšme annĂ©e (1 % ou moins par an), augmentent jusqu'Ă  3,7 % pour la douziĂšme annĂ©e et dĂ©passent les 10 % pour les annĂ©es 14 Ă  16. Le rendement moyen augmente uniformĂ©ment de 0,4 % (7Ăšme annĂ©e) Ă  4,6 % (16Ăšme annĂ©e). La convexitĂ© de la fonction de rĂ©gression logarithmique du salaire implique que ceux qui atteignent un plus haut niveau de scolarisation obtiennent Ă©galement de meilleurs rendements moyens sur le marchĂ© de l'emploi. Nous rejetons l'hypothĂšse nulle selon laquelle les aptitudes non observĂ©es sur le marchĂ© du travail ne sont pas corrĂ©lĂ©es avec les niveaux d'Ă©ducation atteints. Ce rĂ©sultat va Ă  l'encontre de ceux obtenus dans plusieurs Ă©tudes antĂ©rieures qui estimaient le rendement de l'Ă©ducation par la mĂ©thode des MCO. Nous trouvons une corrĂ©lation positive entre le niveau de scolaritĂ© atteint et les aptitudes sur le marchĂ© de l'emploi, confirmant ainsi l'existence d'un «Biais d'aptitude» positif.Return to Schooling, Dynamic Programming, Ability Bias, Discount Rate Bias, Rendements de l'Ă©ducation, Programmation dynamique, Biais d'aptitude, Biais de taux d'escompte
    • 

    corecore