3,281 research outputs found

    Conservation and concealment in SpeciesBanking.com, USA: an analysis of neoliberal performance in the species offsetting industry

    Get PDF
    Market-based strategies are promoted as neoliberal governance solutions to environmental problems, from local to global scales. Tradable mitigation schemes are proliferating. These include species banking, which enables payments for the purchase of species credits awarded to conserved areas to offset development impacts on protected species elsewhere. An analysis of species banks in the USA through a survey of data from the website www.SpeciesBanking.com (established as a ‘clearing house’ for species banking information) was complemented by questionnaire material from USA bank managers. The number of USA species banks has increased rapidly, bank area ownership and management is consolidated in a small number of organizations, and public information on species credit price is limited. In interrogating the case material, the roles of specific economic policies associated with neoliberalism are considered, focusing on the extension of privatization, de- and re-regulation and marketization into the arena of environmental conservation, and commodification processes as manifested in species banking. Problematic ecological and distributive ‘concealments’ in species banking include the ‘development-led’ nature of conservation banking, tendencies towards net biodiversity loss, and an emphasis on supporting conservation-related wealth accumulation by larger landowners and investors

    Letters of concern, condolences, and sympathy from friends and relatives upon the illness and subsequent death of Mr. Fleming on December 20, 1908

    Get PDF
    Correspondents include Bela Bayon. Letters with accompanying envelopes have written answered on them, 1908-12-16 - 1909-02-1

    La croissance espagnole est-elle soutenable ?

    Get PDF
    Depuis le milieu des annĂ©es 1990, et contrairement aux craintes d’un certain nombre de pays europĂ©ens plus avancĂ©s, l’Espagne a fait figure d’excellent Ă©lĂšve au sein de l’Union europĂ©enne : sa croissance a Ă©tĂ© trĂšs forte, l’assainissement des finances publiques a Ă©tĂ© remarquable et le taux de chĂŽmage a entamĂ© une dĂ©crue durable. Cette performance a Ă©tĂ© en grande partie fondĂ©e sur une conjonction exceptionnelle de facteurs favorables (montĂ©e en puissance des fonds structurels, baisse importante des taux d’intĂ©rĂȘt) et s’est principalement appuyĂ©e sur la construction et des services peu productifs. Le rattrapage espagnol a reposĂ© sur l’emploi et sur le renforcement de la spĂ©cialisation de l’économie dans des secteurs Ă  faible valeur ajoutĂ©e, la productivitĂ© du travail s’éloignant au contraire du niveau moyen europĂ©en. L’Espagne a donc de moins en moins pu compter sur la faiblesse de ses coĂ»ts, qui Ă©tait Ă  la base de son attractivitĂ© et de son dĂ©veloppement, du fait d’une inflation toujours plus Ă©levĂ©e que celle de ses principaux partenaires europĂ©ens. De plus, la concurrence des pays de l’Est s’est rĂ©vĂ©lĂ©e de plus en vive. De ce fait, le solde extĂ©rieur n’a cessĂ© de se creuser depuis la fin des annĂ©es 1990. Cet article vise Ă  prĂ©senter le mode de croissance qui a Ă©mergĂ© en Espagne depuis le milieu des annĂ©es 1990 et Ă  rendre compte de ses succĂšs et de ses limites. Il en ressort que la croissance actuelle, tant au niveau de sa composition que de son ampleur, n’est pas soutenable Ă  moyen terme, puisqu’elle est basĂ©e sur des facteurs favorables qui ne se renouvelleront pas et qu’elle a conduit Ă  des dĂ©sĂ©quilibres croissants (forte hausse de la dette des mĂ©nages, surĂ©valuation des prix immobiliers, dĂ©ficit courant record). Ceci implique qu’un rattrapage en termes de productivitĂ© est dĂ©sormais indispensable pour que la convergence espagnole vers l’Union europĂ©enne se poursuive.This article aims to explain why Spanish growth has been so high since the mid-90s (with a significant reduction in public deficit and the unemployment rate), but also why it is not sustainable in the long term. Indeed, growth has recently been greatly dependent on European structural funds and an expansive monetary policy. Furthermore, it has induced severe imbalances (increasing current deficit and household debt, thus generating a house price bubble). For the catching-up towards the European Union to continue, higher productivity growth is necessary

    Latent consequences of early-life lead (Pb) exposure and the future: Addressing the Pb crisis

    Get PDF
    Background. The lead (Pb) exposure crisis in Flint, Michigan has passed from well-publicized event to a footnote, while its biological and social impact will linger for lifetimes. Interest in the “water crisis” has dropped to pre-event levels, which is neither appropriate nor safe. Flint’s exposure was severe, but it was not unique. Problematic Pb levels have also been found in schools and daycares in 42 states in the USA. The enormity of Pb exposure via municipal water systems requires multiple responses. Herein, we focus on addressing a possible answer to long-term sequelae of Pb exposure. We propose “4R’s” (remediation, renovation, reallocation, and research) against the Pb crisis that goes beyond a short-term fix. Remediation for affected individuals must continue to provide clean water and deal with both short and long-term effects of Pb exposure. Renovation of current water delivery systems, at both system-wide and individual site levels, is necessary. Reallocation of resources is needed to ensure these two responses occur and to get communities ready for potential sequelae of Pb exposure. Finally, properly focused research can track exposed individuals and illuminate latent (presumably epigenetic) results of Pb exposure and inform further resource reallocation. Conclusion. Motivation to act by not only the general public but also by scientific and medical leaders must be maintained beyond initial news cycle spikes and an annual follow-up story. Environmental impact of Pb contamination of drinking water goes beyond one exposure incident in an impoverished and forgotten Michigan city. Population effects must be addressed long-term and nationwide

    L'Espagne de Zapatero : rupture ou continuité ?

    Get PDF
    AprĂšs quasiment une dĂ©cennie de pouvoir conservateur (1996-2004), le leader du parti socialiste JosĂ© Luis Rodriguez Zapatero est devenu premier ministre en mars 2004. Il a pris les rĂȘnes d’une Ă©conomie en forte croissance, aprĂšs une importante rĂ©duction du chĂŽmage et un assainissement des finances publiques, permettant au gouvernement de profiter d’amples marges de manƓuvre. Sa tĂąche n’était toutefois pas aisĂ©e, l’économie espagnole souffrant de nombreux dĂ©sĂ©quilibres : une compĂ©titivitĂ© dĂ©gradĂ©e, de faibles gains de productivitĂ©, des prix immobiliers surĂ©valuĂ©s, un creusement du dĂ©ficit courant et une inflation supĂ©rieure Ă  celle de la zone euro. Venaient s’y ajouter un dĂ©ficit social criant et le problĂšme de la prĂ©caritĂ© sur le marchĂ© du travail. À quelques mois de la fin de cette lĂ©gislature, cet article vise Ă  analyser la politique menĂ©e par les socialistes, aprĂšs avoir fait le point sur l’hĂ©ritage Ă©conomique laissĂ© par les conservateurs. Zapatero a entrepris de nombreuses rĂ©formes, avec une montĂ©e en puissance depuis le milieu de son mandat. Les politiques menĂ©es ont visĂ© Ă  soutenir tant l’offre que la demande. Elles ont rĂ©sultĂ© d’un arbitrage dĂ©licat entre l’importance des promesses sociales et la volontĂ© de conserver un excĂ©dent budgĂ©taire. Les avancĂ©es ont Ă©tĂ© rĂ©elles, mais pas d’une ampleur suffisante pour modifier en profondeur le fonctionnement de l’économie espagnole. Les rĂ©formes les plus ambitieuses ont Ă©tĂ© repoussĂ©es, dans l’attente que les nĂ©gociations tripartites aillent plus avant. La politique Ă©conomique de Zapatero s’inscrit en partie dans la lignĂ©e d’Aznar : ce dernier, en imposant une politique budgĂ©taire restrictive pour qualifier l’Espagne Ă  la zone euro, a marquĂ© le dĂ©but d’une nouvelle Ăšre, avec une politique de dĂ©ficit zĂ©ro qui n’a pas Ă©tĂ© remise en cause. Cependant, Zapatero a privilĂ©giĂ© les aspects sociaux et l’investissement, profitant d’une situation budgĂ©taire saine. Les clivages entre la droite et la gauche n’apparaissent pas tant Ă©conomiques que sociĂ©taux, sociaux et liĂ©s Ă  l’exercice du pouvoir. En bref, en matiĂšre Ă©conomique, c’est plus sur la mĂ©thode que Zapatero diverge d’Aznar, avec le retour du processus de concertation.Succeeding the conservative JosĂ© Maria Aznar, the socialist Luis Rodriguez Zapatero became Prime Minister in March 2004. Economics’ growth was strong with an important reduction of unemployment and a public deficit close to zero, but many imbalances were pointed out (low productivity, high inflation, a fall of competitiveness, overvalued house prices, precariousness on labour market and low social security benefits). As the end of his term approaches, this article aims at analyzing his economic policies. Zapatero undertook many reforms (on labour market, pensions...), resulting from a delicate trade-off between the social promises and the will to preserve a budget surplus. But these reforms haven’t been ambitious enough to deeply modify the Spanish economy. Finally, Zapatero’s economic policies seem very similar to those of Aznar, with the exception of social ones and investment
    • 

    corecore