925 research outputs found
Stress and Sleep Quality: Mediating Effects of Social Support
Stress is defined as the ânonspecific response of the body to any demand made upon itâ (Kohn & Frazer, 1986). Stress is among the top five threats to academic performance among college students (Pettit & DeBarr, 2011). The purpose of the study was to investigate whether stress affects perceived sleep quality, as mediated by social support, and to determine whether stress levels vary based on academic major. Using ANOVA in SPSS 24, we tested three hypotheses: stress and sleep quality are negatively correlated, social support mediates the relationship between stress and sleep quality, and stress levels will vary by academic major (specifically that science, technology, engineering, and mathematics majors will show greater perceived amounts of stress). Results of this study show that there is positive correlation between sleep and stress, a negative correlation between social support and sleep, and a negative correlation between stress and social support
Nonequilibrium phase transition in a model for social influence
We present extensive numerical simulations of the Axelrod's model for social
influence, aimed at understanding the formation of cultural domains. This is a
nonequilibrium model with short range interactions and a remarkably rich
dynamical behavior. We study the phase diagram of the model and uncover a
nonequilibrium phase transition separating an ordered (culturally polarized)
phase from a disordered (culturally fragmented) one. The nature of the phase
transition can be continuous or discontinuous depending on the model
parameters. At the transition, the size of cultural regions is power-law
distributed.Comment: 5 pages, 4 figure
Power Law of Customers' Expenditures in Convenience Stores
In a convenience store chain, a tail of the cumulative density function of
the expenditure of a person during a single shopping trip follows a power law
with an exponent of -2.5. The exponent is independent of the location of the
store, the shopper's age, the day of week, and the time of day.Comment: 9 pages, 5 figures. Accepted for publication in Journal of the
Physical Society of Japan Vol.77No.
How to Choose a Champion
League competition is investigated using random processes and scaling
techniques. In our model, a weak team can upset a strong team with a fixed
probability. Teams play an equal number of head-to-head matches and the team
with the largest number of wins is declared to be the champion. The total
number of games needed for the best team to win the championship with high
certainty, T, grows as the cube of the number of teams, N, i.e., T ~ N^3. This
number can be substantially reduced using preliminary rounds where teams play a
small number of games and subsequently, only the top teams advance to the next
round. When there are k rounds, the total number of games needed for the best
team to emerge as champion, T_k, scales as follows, T_k ~N^(\gamma_k) with
gamma_k=1/[1-(2/3)^(k+1)]. For example, gamma_k=9/5,27/19,81/65 for k=1,2,3.
These results suggest an algorithm for how to infer the best team using a
schedule that is linear in N. We conclude that league format is an ineffective
method of determining the best team, and that sequential elimination from the
bottom up is fair and efficient.Comment: 6 pages, 3 figure
The Strategic Exploitation of Limited Information and Opportunity in Networked Markets
This paper studies the effect of constraining interactions within a market. A model is analysed in which boundedly rational agents trade with and gather information from their neighbours within a trade network. It is demonstrated that a traderâs ability to profit and to identify the equilibrium price is positively correlated with its degree of connectivity within the market. Where traders differ in their number of potential trading partners, well-connected traders are found to benefit from aggressive trading behaviour.Where information propagation is constrained by the topology of the trade network, connectedness affects the nature of the strategies employed
Effect of Hund coupling in the one-dimensional SU(4) Hubbard model
The one-dimensional SU(4) Hubbard model perturbed by Hund coupling is
studied, away from half-filling, by means of renormalization group and
bosonization methods. A spectral gap is always present in the spin-orbital
sector irrespective of the magnitude of the Coulomb repulsion. We further
distinguish between two qualitatively different regimes. At small Hund
coupling, we find that the symmetry of the system is dynamically enlarged to
SU(4) at low energy with the result of {\it coherent} spin-orbital excitations.
When the charge sector is not gapped, a superconducting instability is shown to
exist. At large Hund coupling, the symmetry is no longer enlarged to SU(4) and
the excitations in the spin sector become {\it incoherent}. Furthermore, the
superconductivity can be suppressed in favor of the conventional charge density
wave state.Comment: 10 pages, 1 figur
Spinons in a Crossed-Chains Model of a 2D Spin Liquid
Using Random Phase Approximation, we show that a crossed-chains model of a
spin-1/2 Heisenberg spins, with frustrated interchain couplings, has a
non-dimerized spin-liquid ground state in 2D, with deconfined spinons as the
elementary excitations. The results are confirmed by a bosonization study,
which shows that the system is an example of a `sliding Luttinger liquid'. In
an external field, the system develops an incommensurate field-induced long
range order with a finite transition temperature.Comment: 4 pages, 3 figures; added references; scaling analysis, preserving
spin rotational invariance, is extended to finite temperatur
Fractal Profit Landscape of the Stock Market
We investigate the structure of the profit landscape obtained from the most
basic, fluctuation based, trading strategy applied for the daily stock price
data. The strategy is parameterized by only two variables, p and q. Stocks are
sold and bought if the log return is bigger than p and less than -q,
respectively. Repetition of this simple strategy for a long time gives the
profit defined in the underlying two-dimensional parameter space of p and q. It
is revealed that the local maxima in the profit landscape are spread in the
form of a fractal structure. The fractal structure implies that successful
strategies are not localized to any region of the profit landscape and are
neither spaced evenly throughout the profit landscape, which makes the
optimization notoriously hard and hypersensitive for partial or limited
information. The concrete implication of this property is demonstrated by
showing that optimization of one stock for future values or other stocks
renders worse profit than a strategy that ignores fluctuations, i.e., a
long-term buy-and-hold strategy.Comment: 12 pages, 4 figure
- âŠ