13,135 research outputs found

    Production equilibria

    Get PDF
    This paper studies production economies in a commodity space that is an ordered locally convex space. We establish a general theorem on the existence of equilibrium without requiring that the commodity space or its dual be a vector lattice. Such commodity spaces arise in models of portfolio trading where the absence of some option usually means the absence of a vector lattice structure. The conditions on preferences and production sets are at least as general as those imposed in the literature dealing with vector lattice commodity spaces. The main assumption on the order structure is that the Riesz-Kantorovich functionals satisfy a uniform properness condition that can be formulated in terms of a duality property that is readily checked. This condition is satisfied in a vector lattice commodity space but there are many examples of other commodity spaces that satisfy the condition, which are not vector lattices, have no order unit, and do not have either the decomposition property or its approximate versions.Production economies; Equilibrium; Edgeworth equilibrium; Properness; Riesz-Kantorovich functional; Sup-convolution

    Characterization of Riesz spaces with topologically full center

    Full text link
    Let EE be a Riesz space and let Eāˆ¼E^{\sim} denote its order dual. The orthomorphisms Orth(E)Orth(E) on E,E, and the ideal center Z(E)Z(E) of E,E, are naturally embedded in Orth(Eāˆ¼)Orth(E^{\sim}) and Z(Eāˆ¼)Z(E^{\sim}) respectively. We construct two unital algebra and order continuous Riesz homomorphisms Ī³:((Orth(E))āˆ¼)nāˆ¼ā†’Orth(Eāˆ¼)Ā  \gamma:((Orth(E))^{\sim})_{n}^{\sim}\rightarrow Orth(E^{\sim})\text{ }% and m:Z(E)ā€²ā€²ā†’Z(Eāˆ¼) m:Z(E)^{\prime\prime}\rightarrow Z(E^{\sim}) that extend the above mentioned natural inclusions respectively. Then, the range of Ī³\gamma is an order ideal in Orth(Eāˆ¼)Orth(E^{\sim}) if and only if mm is surjective. Furthermore, mm is surjective if and only if EE has a topologically full center. (That is, the Ļƒ(E,Eāˆ¼)\sigma(E,E^{\sim})-closure of Z(E)xZ(E)x contains the order ideal generated by xx for each xāˆˆE+.x\in E_{+}.) As a consequence, EE has a topologically full center Z(E)Z(E) if and only if Z(Eāˆ¼)=Ļ€ā‹…Z(E)ā€²ā€²Z(E^{\sim})=\pi\cdot Z(E)^{\prime\prime} for some idempotent $\pi\in Z(E)^{\prime\prime}.

    Frames for the solution of operator equations in Hilbert spaces with fixed dual pairing

    Get PDF
    For the solution of operator equations, Stevenson introduced a definition of frames, where a Hilbert space and its dual are {\em not} identified. This means that the Riesz isomorphism is not used as an identification, which, for example, does not make sense for the Sobolev spaces H01(Ī©)H_0^1(\Omega) and Hāˆ’1(Ī©)H^{-1}(\Omega). In this article, we are going to revisit the concept of Stevenson frames and introduce it for Banach spaces. This is equivalent to ā„“2\ell^2-Banach frames. It is known that, if such a system exists, by defining a new inner product and using the Riesz isomorphism, the Banach space is isomorphic to a Hilbert space. In this article, we deal with the contrasting setting, where H\mathcal H and Hā€²\mathcal H' are not identified, and equivalent norms are distinguished, and show that in this setting the investigation of ā„“2\ell^2-Banach frames make sense.Comment: 23 pages; accepted for publication in 'Numerical Functional Analysis and Optimization
    • ā€¦
    corecore