506,681 research outputs found

    Π—Π°Ρ€ΡƒΠ±Ρ–ΠΆΠ½ΠΈΠΉ досвід Ρ‰ΠΎΠ΄ΠΎ ΠΏΡ€Π°Π²ΠΎΠ²ΠΎΠ³ΠΎ Ρ€Π΅ΠΆΠΈΠΌΡƒ Π·Π΅ΠΌΠ΅Π»ΡŒΠ½ΠΎΡ— ділянки Ρ– Ρ€ΠΎΠ·Ρ‚Π°ΡˆΠΎΠ²Π°Π½ΠΎΠ³ΠΎ Π½Π° Π½Ρ–ΠΉ Π½Π΅Ρ€ΡƒΡ…ΠΎΠΌΠΎΠ³ΠΎ ΠΌΠ°ΠΉΠ½Π°

    No full text
    Π‘Ρ‚Π°Ρ‚ΡŒΡ посвящСна ΠΎΠΏΡ€Π΅Π΄Π΅Π»Π΅Π½ΠΈΡŽ ΠΏΡ€Π°Π²ΠΎΠ²Ρ‹Ρ… особСнностСй дСлСния собствСнности Π½Π° Π΄Π²ΠΈΠΆΠΈΠΌΠΎΠ΅ ΠΈ Π½Π΅Π΄Π²ΠΈΠΆΠΈΠΌΠΎΠ΅ имущСство, Π² частности: ΠΎΠ±Ρ‰Π΅ΠΉ характСристикС ΠΎΠ±ΡŠΠ΅ΠΊΡ‚ΠΎΠ² нСдвиТимости, ΠΊΠΎΡ‚ΠΎΡ€Ρ‹Π΅ Π½Π΅ΠΎΡ‚Ρ€Ρ‹Π²Π½ΠΎ привязаны ΠΊ Π·Π΅ΠΌΠ»Π΅, ΠΈΡ… ΠΏΡ€Π°Π²ΠΎΠ²ΠΎΠΉ Ρ€Π΅ΠΆΠΈΠΌ, порядок использования зСмСльного участка ΠΈ находящСгося Π½Π° Π½Π΅ΠΌ Π½Π΅Π΄Π²ΠΈΠΆΠΈΠΌΠΎΠ³ΠΎ имущСства ΠΏΠΎ Π·Π°ΠΊΠΎΠ½ΠΎΠ΄Π°Ρ‚Π΅Π»ΡŒΡΡ‚Π²Ρƒ Π·Π°Ρ€ΡƒΠ±Π΅ΠΆΠ½Ρ‹Ρ… стран. ΠšΠ»ΡŽΡ‡Π΅Π²Ρ‹Π΅ слова: ΠΏΡ€Π°Π²ΠΎΠ²ΠΎΠΉ Ρ€Π΅ΠΆΠΈΠΌ зСмСльного участка, Π΄Π²ΠΈΠΆΠΈΠΌΠΎΠ΅ ΠΈ Π½Π΅Π΄Π²ΠΈΠΆΠΈΠΌΠΎΠ΅ имущСство, Π΅Π΄ΠΈΠ½Ρ‹ΠΉ ΠΎΠ±ΡŠΠ΅ΠΊΡ‚ нСдвиТимости, ΠΏΡ€Π°Π²ΠΎ собствСнности Π½Π° зСмлю, ΠΏΡ€ΠΈΠ½Ρ†ΠΈΠΏ Β«Π΅Π΄ΠΈΠ½ΠΎΠΉ ΡΡƒΠ΄ΡŒΠ±Ρ‹Β», ΠΎΠ±Ρ‰Π΅Π΅ ΠΎΡ‚Ρ‡ΡƒΠΆΠ΄Π΅Π½ΠΈΠ΅ участка ΠΈ строСний, здания ΠΈ строСния Π½Π° Β«Ρ‡ΡƒΠΆΠΈΡ…Β» Π·Π΅ΠΌΠ΅Π»ΡŒΠ½Ρ‹Ρ… участках.This article is dedicated to legal features on property division to personal chattels and real estate, namely: general characteristic of real estate objects, which are continuously tied to the land, their legal mode, the order of land plot use and real estate under the laws of foreign countries. Key words: legal mode of land plot, real estate and personal property, common real estate object, property law on land plot, principle of Β«common destinyΒ», general alienation of land plot and building, buildings and constructions on Β«foreign landsΒ»

    Power laws in real estate prices during bubble periods

    Get PDF
    How can we detect real estate bubbles? In this paper, we propose making use of information on the cross-sectional dispersion of real estate prices. During bubble periods, prices tend to go up considerably for some properties, but less so for others, so that price inequality across properties increases. In other words, a key characteristic of real estate bubbles is not the rapid price hike itself but a rise in price dispersion. Given this, the purpose of this paper is to examine whether developments in the dispersion in real estate prices can be used to detect bubbles in property markets as they arise, using data from Japan and the U.S. First, we show that the land price distribution in Tokyo had a power-law tail during the bubble period in the late 1980s, while it was very close to a lognormal before and after the bubble period. Second, in the U.S. data we find that the tail of the house price distribution tends to be heavier in those states which experienced a housing bubble. We also provide evidence suggesting that the power-law tail observed during bubble periods arises due to the lack of price arbitrage across regions.Econophysics, Power law, Bubbles, House prices, Land prices, Price dispersion

    POWER LAWS IN REAL ESTATE PRICES DURING BUBBLE PERIODS

    Get PDF
    How can we detect real estate bubbles? In this paper, we propose making use of information on the cross-sectional dispersion of real estate prices. During bubble periods, prices tend to go up considerably for some properties, but less so for others, so that price inequality across properties increases. In other words, a key characteristic of real estate bubbles is not the rapid price hike itself but a rise in price dispersion. Given this, the purpose of this paper is to examine whether developments in the dispersion in real estate prices can be used to detect bubbles in property markets as they arise, using data from Japan and the U.S. First, we show that the land price distribution in Tokyo had a power-law tail during the bubble period in the late 1980s, while it was very close to a lognormal before and after the bubble period. Second, in the U.S. data we find that the tail of the house price distribution tends to be heavier in those states which experienced a housing bubble. We also provide evidence suggesting that the power-law tail observed during bubble periods arises due to the lack of price arbitrage across regions.

    Clearing the Air on Radon Testing: The Duty of Real Estate Brokers to Protect Prospective Homebuyers

    Get PDF
    This Note recommends that the federal government create legislation that will impose a duty on real estate brokers to test homes for radon and to disclose the results to prospective purchasers. Based on a common law negligence theory, such a duty would become part of the current obligation of a real estate broker: (1) to conduct a reasonably diligent and competent search of property for sale; and (2) to disclose to prospective homebuyers all material defects affecting the value or desirability of the home. In his investigation, the broker must use the expertise and knowledge that derive from his training and experience as a professional. Initially, the Note addresses the dilemma of the homebuyer who discovers radon only after occupying the home and who has no formally defined cause of action based on common law precedent or statute. Part II traces the development of a real estate broker\u27s liability in negligence to the recently imposed duty to discover and disclose latent defects. Part III analyzes the duty to discover and disclose latent defects with respect to radon and concludes that real estate brokers should have an affirmative duty to test for radon and to disclose the results to prospective purchasers. Finally, part IV recommends legislation to protect the unwary homebuyer who otherwise would take possession of the home and suffer potential economic loss and exposure to a carcinogenic substance

    Clearing the Air on Radon Testing: The Duty of Real Estate Brokers to Protect Prospective Homebuyers

    Get PDF
    This Note recommends that the federal government create legislation that will impose a duty on real estate brokers to test homes for radon and to disclose the results to prospective purchasers. Based on a common law negligence theory, such a duty would become part of the current obligation of a real estate broker: (1) to conduct a reasonably diligent and competent search of property for sale; and (2) to disclose to prospective homebuyers all material defects affecting the value or desirability of the home. In his investigation, the broker must use the expertise and knowledge that derive from his training and experience as a professional. Initially, the Note addresses the dilemma of the homebuyer who discovers radon only after occupying the home and who has no formally defined cause of action based on common law precedent or statute. Part II traces the development of a real estate broker\u27s liability in negligence to the recently imposed duty to discover and disclose latent defects. Part III analyzes the duty to discover and disclose latent defects with respect to radon and concludes that real estate brokers should have an affirmative duty to test for radon and to disclose the results to prospective purchasers. Finally, part IV recommends legislation to protect the unwary homebuyer who otherwise would take possession of the home and suffer potential economic loss and exposure to a carcinogenic substance

    Tearing Down the Wall: How Transfer-on-Death Real-Estate Deeds Challenge the Inter Vivos/Testamentary Divide

    Get PDF
    This Article will examine one of the most recent will substitutes, the transfer-on-death (β€œTOD”) real-estate deed. Nearly half of the states have recognized, through common-law forms or legislation, a mechanism to allow for the transfer of real property on death without using a will, without following the will formalities, and without necessitating probate. This new tool in the estate planner’s toolbox is invaluable: revocable trusts have proven too expensive for decedents of modest means, and wills continue to require formalities that can easily frustrate non-lawyer-drafted estate documents. But the variety of TOD deed rules and mechanisms that the different states have adopted has led to disparity and uncertainty in form and outcome, resulting in litigation and frustration of decedent’s intent. We believe this uncertainty and frustration will continue as even more states adopt the Uniform Real Property Transfer on Death Act (β€œURPTODA”), which purports to stabilize the law and facilitate testamentary intent. States grappling with this new form interpose significant differences, and lawyers and judges are not all on the same page as to the consequences. One source of confusion is the URPTODA’s provision that TOD deeds are non-testamentary and, at the same time, the Uniform Act provides that the property rights do not transfer until death. Although it is one thing to declare that TOD deeds are non-testamentary even though property rights don’t transfer until deathβ€”which in itself goes against centuries of formal legal rulesβ€”it is quite another to get all the other legal consequences to fall into place accordingly. For instance, would a state’s anti-lapse statute apply to save a beneficiary designation if the deed is deemed non-testamentary, even though the intent is to have the real property transfer upon death? In our opinion, the TOD deed pushes the juridical binary of inter vivos and testamentary transfers beyond coherence and rationality. The law of will substitutes has already undermined the rationality of maintaining the divide, and in this Article, we will argue that the time has finally come to reject the division between inter vivos and testamentary transfers and seek a rational and holistic set of tools and formalities to gain the benefits of probate avoidance that will substitutes provide with the ease of control and full revocability of wills. Elevating form over functionality, although a characteristic of the common law, inevitably disserves the interests of those who cannot afford lawyers who can easily draft around the sometimes-arcane distinctions between testamentary and inter vivos transfers to gain the benefits of each while avoiding the burdens

    Building a Commercial Practice

    Get PDF
    Commercial real estate law practice includes but is not limited to everything from new construction to complex exchanges, from strip shopping centers with a few stores to modern regional shopping centers, from the small two or three unit office building to the large downtown and suburban office/residential condo developments, and the sale of any type of business property. While it appears there is room for thousands of attorneys to handle the major transactions described above, this is generally not the case. It is well known that the commercial real estate bar in most large metropolitan areas is a rather select group. Is there a place in this group for the young lawyer

    Rushing to Overpay: The REIT Premium Revisited

    Get PDF
    We explore the questions of whether and why Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) pay more for real estate than non-REIT buyers, consequently breaking the law of one price. We develop a model where REITs optimally pay more for property because (1) they are able, due to capital access advantages and, (2) are occasionally compelled, due to regulatory time constraints on the deployment of capital. We show that the typically large (20 to 60 percent) and statistically significant (p-values less than 0.01) REIT-buyer premiums found in standard empirical hedonic pricing models are biased due to unobserved explanatory variables. Using a repeat-transaction methodology that controls for unobserved independent variables, we find the REIT-buyer premium to be about 5 percent. Furthermore, we show that REITsΒΏ ability (as measured by access to capital markets) and regulator compulsion (as measured by capital deployment deadlines) are related to the price premium.Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs), commercial properties, hedonic price analysis, repeat transactions, market efficiency, law of one price, price premium

    Who has really paid for the Reconstruction of East Germany? Expected and Realized Returns on Real Estate Investments in East and West Germany in the 1990s

    Get PDF
    This paper explores cultural differences in risky choices between Australian and German students. The purpose of this paper is to challenge the wide-spread view that investment in residential property in East Germany after unification has turned out to be a financial disaster in most cases by calculating (1) the after-tax return an investor in real property might have expected at the beginning of the 1990s and (2) the after-tax return that has been realized ten years after. We compare investments by a high-income investor resident in Germany in an average individually-owned flat in three major cities in East Germany and two cities in West Germany. The result of our study is that tax subsidies have protected investors from loosing money in a real estate investment. Therefore, it was indeed the taxpayers not the investors who have borne the cost of reconstructing East Germany. But taxpayers have spent a lot more on subsidising the much bigger West German housing market where property prices and tax subsidies per average investment were much higher.real-estate investment, after-tax return on investment, tax subsidies, Assisted Area Law (FΓΆrdergebietsgesetz), empirical study, income tax reduction, loss offset, special depreciation, return on equity capital (ROE), property prices

    Private Property Investment, Lucas and the Fairness Doctrine

    Get PDF
    These remarks are not intended to advocate the interests of the new property rights movement. In fact, those advocates will be disappointed by what I say. Rather, I aspire to view the issue of real property regulation as broadly as possible, reaching beyond the jurisprudence of regulatory takings cases into the realms of real estate transactions law and comprehensive land use planning
    • …
    corecore